- Spitfire List - https://spitfirelist.com -

The US Falls Down the GOP’s Tax Scam Memory Hole. Again.

When is a tax cut more than just a tax cut? When it’s a GOP tax cut. Because when the GOP cuts tax­es, it’s nev­er just an attempt to cut tax­es because tax cuts are just one ele­ment of the GOP’s much larg­er agen­da of cre­at­ing a soci­ety run by and for the super-rich. And because few peo­ple, even Repub­li­can vot­ers, actu­al­ly want a soci­ety that’s run by and for the super-rich, mas­sive amounts of pro­pa­gan­da and decep­tion are part of the tax cut pack­age too. It’s why GOP tax cuts tend to be so much more than just tax cuts for the rich. They’re Big Lies designed to fool soci­ety into dis­man­tling itself.

So it should come as a sur­prise to no one that the cur­rent tax cut bar­rel­ing its way through the GOP con­trolled con­gress is an abom­i­na­tion being sold to the pub­lic by a web of lies that rep­re­sent an inver­sion of the truth. But what is gen­uine­ly sur­pris­ing about the cur­rent GOP tax push is just how shod­dy that web of lies is turn­ing out to be this time. Per­haps it should­n’t be sur­pris­ing giv­en the polit­i­cal dis­as­ter that the GOP’s mul­ti­ple failed attempts to over­turn Oba­macare turned out to be, where less than 1 in 5 vot­ers actu­al­ly approved of ‘Trump­care’ once they learned about Trump­care’s details and this was the case for both the House and Sen­ate ver­sions of Trump­care [1]. The GOP clear­ly has prob­lems craft­ing leg­is­la­tion that it can at least try and pre­tend is ‘for the peo­ple’ these days so trou­bles craft­ing the tax cuts aren’t par­tic­u­lar­ly sur­pris­ing. But as we’re going to see, the Trump tax cut are turn­ing out to be so polit­i­cal­ly tox­ic that it’s very pos­si­ble that the GOP’s tax bill will end up being even more polit­i­cal­ly poi­so­nous than ‘Trump­care’. And that is gen­uine­ly sur­pris­ing. It’s almost as if the fail­ure to pass Trump­care only increased the resolve of Amer­i­ca’s right-wing oli­garchs to vin­dic­tive­ly pass leg­is­la­tion that’s even more awful [2]:

Asso­ci­at­ed Press

Ultra-Rich Win Big Under GOP Tax Bill; Tax­es Rise For Every­one Else

By MARCY GORDON
Pub­lished Novem­ber 18, 2017 9:28 am

WASHINGTON (AP) — The ultra-wealthy, espe­cial­ly those with dynas­tic busi­ness­es — like Pres­i­dent Don­ald Trump and his fam­i­ly — do very well under a major Repub­li­can tax bill mov­ing in the Sen­ate, as they do under leg­is­la­tion passed this week by the House.

Want to toast the antic­i­pat­ed tax win with cham­pagne or a beer — or maybe you’re feel­ing Shake­speare­an and pre­fer to quaff mead from a pewter mug? That would cheer pro­duc­ers of beer, wine, liquor — and mead, the ancient bev­er­age fer­ment­ed from hon­ey. Tax rates on their sales would be reduced under the Sen­ate bill.

On the oth­er hand, peo­ple liv­ing in high-tax states, who deduct their local prop­er­ty, income and sales tax­es from what they owe Uncle Sam, could lose out from the com­plete or par­tial repeal of the deduc­tions. And an esti­mat­ed 13 mil­lion Amer­i­cans could lose health insur­ance cov­er­age over 10 years under the Sen­ate bill.

Some win­ners and losers:
__

WINNERS

Wealthy indi­vid­u­als and their heirs win big. The hottest class-war­fare debate around the tax over­haul leg­is­la­tion involves the inher­i­tance tax on mul­ti­mil­lion-dol­lar estates. Democ­rats wave the legislation’s tar­get­ing of the tax as a red flag in the face of Repub­li­cans, as proof that they’re out to ben­e­fit wealthy donors. The House bill ini­tial­ly dou­bles the lim­its — to $11 mil­lion for indi­vid­u­als and $22 mil­lion for cou­ples — on how much mon­ey in the estate can be exempt­ed from the inher­i­tance tax, then repeals it entire­ly after 2023. The Sen­ate ver­sion also dou­bles the lim­its but doesn’t repeal the tax.

Then there’s the alter­na­tive min­i­mum tax, a levy aimed at ensur­ing that high­er-earn­ing peo­ple pay at least some tax. It dis­ap­pears in both bills.

And the House mea­sure cuts tax rates for many of the mil­lions of “pass-through” busi­ness­es big and small — includ­ing part­ner­ships and spe­cial­ly orga­nized cor­po­ra­tions — whose prof­its are taxed at the own­ers’ per­son­al income rate. That’s poten­tial cha-ching for Trump’s far-flung prop­er­ty empire and the hold­ings of his daugh­ter Ivan­ka and her hus­band, Jared Kush­n­er. The Sen­ate bill lets pass-through own­ers deduct some of the earn­ings and then pay at their per­son­al income rate on the remain­der.

— Cor­po­ra­tions win all around, with a tax rate slashed from 35 per­cent to 20 per­cent in both bills — though they’d have to wait a year for it under the Sen­ate mea­sure. Trump and the admin­is­tra­tion view it as an untouch­able cen­ter­piece of the leg­is­la­tion.

— U.S. oil com­pa­nies with for­eign oper­a­tions would pay reduced tax­es under the Sen­ate bill on their income from sales of oil and nat­ur­al gas abroad.

— Beer, wine and liquor pro­duc­ers would reap tax reduc­tions under the Sen­ate mea­sure.

— Com­pa­nies that pro­vide man­age­ment ser­vices like main­te­nance for air­craft get an updat­ed win. The Sen­ate bill clar­i­fies that under cur­rent law, the man­age­ment com­pa­nies would be exempt from pay­ing tax­es on pay­ments they receive from own­ers of pri­vate jets as well as from com­mer­cial air­lines. That was a request from Ohio Sens. Rob Port­man, a Repub­li­can, and Sher­rod Brown, a Demo­c­rat, whose state is home to Net­Jets, a big air­craft man­age­ment com­pa­ny.

Port­man vot­ed for the over­all bill. Brown opposed it.
__

LOSERS

— An esti­mat­ed 13 mil­lion Amer­i­cans could lose health insur­ance cov­er­age under the Sen­ate bill, which would repeal the “Oba­macare” require­ment that every­one in the U.S. have health insur­ance. The pro­jec­tion comes from the non­par­ti­san Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office. Elim­i­nat­ing the fines is expect­ed to mean few­er peo­ple would obtain fed­er­al­ly sub­si­dized health poli­cies.

— Peo­ple liv­ing in high-tax states would be hit by repeal of fed­er­al deduc­tions for state and local tax­es under the Sen­ate bill, and par­tial repeal under the House mea­sure. That result of a com­pro­mise allows the deduc­tion for up to $10,000 in prop­er­ty tax­es.

— Many fam­i­lies mak­ing less than $30,000 a year would face tax increas­es start­ing in 2021 under the Sen­ate bill, accord­ing to Con­gress’ non­par­ti­san Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion. By 2027, fam­i­lies earn­ing less than $75,000 would see their tax bills rise while those mak­ing more would enjoy reduc­tions, the ana­lysts find. The indi­vid­ual income-tax reduc­tions in the Sen­ate bill would end in 2026.

———-

“Ultra-Rich Win Big Under GOP Tax Bill; Tax­es Rise For Every­one Else” by MARCY GORDON; Asso­ci­at­ed Press; 11/18/2017 [2]

Wealthy indi­vid­u­als and their heirs win big. The hottest class-war­fare debate around the tax over­haul leg­is­la­tion involves the inher­i­tance tax on mul­ti­mil­lion-dol­lar estates. Democ­rats wave the legislation’s tar­get­ing of the tax as a red flag in the face of Repub­li­cans, as proof that they’re out to ben­e­fit wealthy donors. The House bill ini­tial­ly dou­bles the lim­its — to $11 mil­lion for indi­vid­u­als and $22 mil­lion for cou­ples — on how much mon­ey in the estate can be exempt­ed from the inher­i­tance tax, then repeals it entire­ly after 2023. The Sen­ate ver­sion also dou­bles the lim­its but doesn’t repeal the tax.”

As we can see, the wealthy and their heirs are the big win­ners in both the House and Sen­ate ver­sions of the bills. Sur­prise!

But don’t for­get that it’s not just things like the elim­i­na­tion of the estate tax or cuts to the indi­vid­ual rates for the wealthy that are going to make this tax cut a giant gift to the wealthy. The mas­sive cut to the cor­po­rate tax, from 35 to 20 per­cent, also counts as a mas­sive tax cut for the rich giv­en the real­i­ty that 80 per­cent of the stock mar­ket wealth in the US is owned by the wealth­i­est 10 per­cent [3] and the top 1% of Amer­i­cans own 38 per­cent the US’s wealth over­all [4]. When the rich own almost every­thing you can’t cut cor­po­rate tax­es with­out cut­ting tax­es dis­pro­por­tion­ate­ly for the rich and that per­ma­nent cor­po­rate tax cut down to 20 per­cent is part of both the House and Sen­ate bills.

But while it’s clear that both the House and Sen­ate ver­sions of the bill rep­re­sent a mas­sive redis­tri­b­u­tion of wealth towards the already-wealthy, there are still a num­ber of dif­fer­ences between the House and Sen­ate ver­sions and at some point those dif­fer­ences are going to have to be resolved. And as we’re going to see, the res­o­lu­tion of those dif­fer­ences isn’t going to be easy for two key inter­re­lat­ed rea­sons:

1. The Sen­ate’s “Byrd rule” needs to be fol­lowed to in order to pass leg­is­la­tion in the Sen­ate with a sim­ple major­i­ty vote of 51 Sen­a­tors, avoid­ing the 60-vote thresh­old to over­come a fil­i­buster. And the Byrd rule stip­u­lates that new spend­ing leg­is­la­tion must be bud­get-neu­tral over the next 10 years. That’s a pret­ty big ‘catch’ to the Byrd rule when you’re plan­ning a mas­sive tax give­away for cor­po­ra­tions and the wealthy.

and

2. The GOP’s tax cuts are not remote­ly budget-neutral...unless you decide to drink the ‘trick­le-down’ sup­ply-side eco­nom­ics Kool-Aid and choose to believe the fan­ta­sy that mas­sive tax cuts for the wealthy will per­ma­nent­ly tur­bo-charge the US econ­o­my. The vast major­i­ty of econ­o­mists believe no such fan­ta­sy, and with good rea­son giv­en that his­tor­i­cal evi­dence does­n’t sup­port it (it’s not like this will be the first time the US has giv­en the rich a mas­sive tax cut). But unless the GOP can suc­cess­ful­ly sell the US on the notion that mas­sive tax cuts for the rich and cor­po­ra­tions will result in a large and per­ma­nent increase in the growth of the US econ­o­my it’s going to be very dif­fi­cult for the GOP to con­struct a tax plan that cuts tax­es on the wealthy and cor­po­ra­tions that’s bud­get neu­tral. The math just won’t work with­out the ‘trick­le-down’ Kool-Aid.

And that Byrd rule require­ment that the Sen­ate alone faces is key dri­ver for the dif­fer­ences we’re going to see between the House and Sen­ate ver­sions of the tax cuts: the House does­n’t need to adhere to the Byrd rule, so its ver­sion of the bill involves a lot more cuts with a high­er explo­sion of pub­lic debt. The Sen­ate ver­sion, on the oth­er hand, has to some­how find a way to bal­ance out the tax cuts for the wealthy with new rev­enues that some­how all bal­ance out with­in a decade. And in order find that bal­ance the Sen­ate bill actu­al­ly ends up rais­ing tax­es on the poor and mid­dle-class and Demo­c­ra­t­ic-lean­ing states. And also encour­ages poor-peo­ple to drop their sub­si­dized health insur­ance. Yep, that’s how the Sen­ate ver­sion of the bill pass­es the Byrd rule. By pass­ing the cost of the tax cuts for the wealthy on to the mid­dle-class, the poor, and ‘Blue states’.

So with that crit­i­cal dis­tinc­tion between the House and Sen­ate bills in mind — the Sen­ate needs to fol­low the Byrd rule and avoid explod­ing the deficit, the House does­n’t — it’s worth tak­ing a clos­er look at the var­i­ous sim­i­lar­i­ties and dif­fer­ences between the House and Sen­ate ver­sions of the bill. They are both extreme­ly gen­er­ous to the wealthy and cor­po­ra­tions, but the House ver­sion tends to be some­what more gen­er­ous with­out try­ing to cov­er the cost of that gen­eros­i­ty: Both ver­sions also elim­i­nate the the alter­na­tive min­i­mum tax (mean­ing a lot of wealthy peo­ple will be allowed to pay almost noth­ing in tax­es) and both ver­sions dou­ble the the inher­i­tance tax exemp­tion from estates worth $11 mil­lion up to $22 mil­lion right away, but only in the House ver­sion has the entire estate tax expire in 2023. Also, both ver­sions cuts in the tax rate for “pass-through” busi­ness­es — where prof­its are taxed at the per­son­al income tax rate (which tends to be high­er than the cor­po­rate tax rate for wealth indi­vid­u­als) — but the House ver­sion is par­tic­u­lar­ly nice to the wealthy who own pass-through cor­po­ra­tions:

...
Then there’s the alter­na­tive min­i­mum tax, a levy aimed at ensur­ing that high­er-earn­ing peo­ple pay at least some tax. It dis­ap­pears in both bills.

And the House mea­sure cuts tax rates for many of the mil­lions of “pass-through” busi­ness­es big and small — includ­ing part­ner­ships and spe­cial­ly orga­nized cor­po­ra­tions — whose prof­its are taxed at the own­ers’ per­son­al income rate. That’s poten­tial cha-ching for Trump’s far-flung prop­er­ty empire and the hold­ings of his daugh­ter Ivan­ka and her hus­band, Jared Kush­n­er. The Sen­ate bill lets pass-through own­ers deduct some of the earn­ings and then pay at their per­son­al income rate on the remain­der.
...

An elim­i­na­tion of the estate tax and and a with a 25 per­cent tax rate for “pass-through” cor­po­ra­tions [5]. Yeah, the House ver­sion of the bill is going to be mighty nice for peo­ple like Ivan­ka Trump and Jared Kush­n­er. And it’s not like the Sen­ate ver­sion isn’t still wild­ly gen­er­ous to Jared and Ivan­ka. It’s not quite as gen­er­ous.

And look one of the major ways the Sen­ate ver­sion helps pay for cost all these good­ies for the wealthy: by repeal­ing the “Oba­macare” man­date, the require­ment that US adults pur­chase health insur­ance or face a small annu­al fine. The Sen­ate ver­sion com­plies with the Byrd rule by assum­ing that repeal­ing the Oba­macare man­date will result in an esti­mate 13 mil­lion Amer­i­cans drop­ping their health insur­ance cov­er­age. Cov­er­age that is typ­i­cal­ly gov­ern­ment sub­si­dized. The tax cuts for the rich are paid for with less health care for the poor. That’s how the Sen­ate bill is lit­er­al­ly designed. And that’s on top of the Sen­ate’s plan to have tax­es on peo­ple mak­ing less than $75,000 actu­al­ly rise at the end of 10 years:

...
An esti­mat­ed 13 mil­lion Amer­i­cans could lose health insur­ance cov­er­age under the Sen­ate bill, which would repeal the “Oba­macare” require­ment that every­one in the U.S. have health insur­ance. The pro­jec­tion comes from the non­par­ti­san Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office. Elim­i­nat­ing the fines is expect­ed to mean few­er peo­ple would obtain fed­er­al­ly sub­si­dized health poli­cies.

— Peo­ple liv­ing in high-tax states would be hit by repeal of fed­er­al deduc­tions for state and local tax­es under the Sen­ate bill, and par­tial repeal under the House mea­sure. That result of a com­pro­mise allows the deduc­tion for up to $10,000 in prop­er­ty tax­es.

— Many fam­i­lies mak­ing less than $30,000 a year would face tax increas­es start­ing in 2021 under the Sen­ate bill, accord­ing to Con­gress’ non­par­ti­san Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion. By 2027, fam­i­lies earn­ing less than $75,000 would see their tax bills rise while those mak­ing more would enjoy reduc­tions, the ana­lysts find. The indi­vid­ual income-tax reduc­tions in the Sen­ate bill would end in 2026.
...

The Sen­ate GOP’s giant tax cut is set to raise tax­es on the poor to pay for tax cuts for the rich and cor­po­ra­tions. It’s that bad and that bla­tant. With the House ver­sion we don’t find as many tax hikes on the poor and mid­dle-class, but it just ends up blow­ing up the nation­al debt more instead. But the the mid­dle-class and poor don’t fair much bet­ter with the House bill, where mid­dle-class tax cuts expire and only 40 per­cent of Amer­i­cans will still see low­er tax­es by 2023, along with pop­u­lar deduc­tions like the mort­gage deduc­tion in the House ver­sion [6].

House Lead­er­ship to GOP­ers: Don’t Trash the Sen­ate Bill (Because it’s Prob­a­bly Clos­er to the Final Bill)

But despite all the sim­i­lar­i­ties between the two ver­sions of the bill — they both show­er cor­po­ra­tions and the wealthy with tax treats and make the poor and mid­dle-class pay for them — there are still sig­nif­i­cant dif­fer­ences. So which ver­sion should we expect to win out? Well, since the Byrd rule still applies to the final ver­sion of the bill that the Sen­ate has to vote on — the ver­sion the House and the Sen­ate cre­ate in con­fer­ence after the dif­fer­ent ver­sions of the bill are passed by each cham­ber — it’s hard to see how the Sen­ate’s ver­sion isn’t going to be a lot clos­er to the final ver­sion of the bill because that’s the only way the final ver­sion can still com­ply with the Byrd rule. And that’s why it’s no sur­prise that we have reports that the House lead­er­ship told law­mak­ers not to bash the Sen­ate tax bill which is mak­ing some House mem­bers feel like the even­tu­al plan for the House is to make their ver­sion of the tax cut look a lot more like the Sen­ate ver­sion [7]:

Vox

The House just passed its tax reform plan. It’s dras­ti­cal­ly dif­fer­ent from the Senate’s.

by Tara Gol­shan Nov 16, 2017, 1:51pm EST Updat­ed

House Repub­li­cans passed their tax reform plan Thurs­day after­noon 227–205 — on a day marked by a vis­it from Pres­i­dent Don­ald Trump — with only 13 Repub­li­cans vot­ing against it.

It was a big day for House Speak­er Paul Ryan. On the sur­face, the pro­pos­al, which dra­mat­i­cal­ly cuts tax­es for cor­po­ra­tions, dou­bles the stan­dard deduc­tion, and con­sol­i­dates the indi­vid­ual tax rates, among oth­er changes, has moved swift­ly through the House with­out much dra­ma. “This is Ryan’s bill,” Rep. Pete Ses­sions (R‑TX) told reporters.

But behind the cheers and cel­e­bra­tion, there’s a clear sense that this vote doesn’t say much about the state of tax reform as a whole — a debate that, despite the insis­tence of Repub­li­can lead­er­ship and their allies, is still unre­solved.

As the House passed its bill, on the oth­er side of the Capi­tol Build­ing the Sen­ate con­tin­ues to mark up its own tax reform pro­pos­al — one that looks very dif­fer­ent from the House’s.

“It is inter­est­ing to me that the ‘Big Six’ worked for nine months on get­ting on the same sheet of music on tax reform, and [to] have it be this dynam­i­cal­ly dif­fer­ent as it is rolled out — it’s a bit of a sur­prise,” Rep. Mark Mead­ows (R‑NC) told Vox of the group of top sen­a­tors, House mem­bers, and Trump admin­is­tra­tion offi­cials who brain­stormed a frame­work for tax reform.

Going into the vote, House lead­er­ship told law­mak­ers not to bash the Sen­ate tax bill — a move that has made some feel like the plan is to adopt a lot more of the Sen­ate bill. Already, some of the dif­fer­ences are mak­ing House Repub­li­cans grum­ble. The Sen­ate ful­ly repeals the state and local income and prop­er­ty tax deduc­tion, cuts health care, and sun­sets tax relief for indi­vid­ual Amer­i­cans in order to pay for cor­po­rate tax cuts.

“You’re rewrit­ing a tax code for a gen­er­a­tion, and you are doing it in 10 days, and then to be dis­man­tling health care with­out any debate at all could have unin­tend­ed con­se­quences,” Rep. Peter King (R‑NY), who vot­ed against the House bill, said. “In [1986] it took two years to put togeth­er a tax reform bill; they’re doing it in 10 days.”

We still don’t know exact­ly what tax reform will look like — but Repub­li­cans are mov­ing fast

“It seems to be pret­ty sig­nif­i­cant dif­fer­ences,” King told Vox Wednes­day of the House and Sen­ate tax reform pro­pos­als.

“Espe­cial­ly because you have to get it done in such a short amount of time. Any changes to the tax bill has sig­nif­i­cant con­se­quences,” he con­tin­ued.

The day before the House vote, some mem­bers cast last-minute doubts on the math, Huff­Post report­ed [8], ques­tion­ing whether the typ­i­cal fam­i­ly of four would actu­al­ly get an aver­age cut of $1,182, as Repub­li­can lead­er­ship keeps tout­ing.

There’s no ques­tion that Repub­li­cans have been grap­pling with a major math prob­lem with their tax bill, search­ing for bud­get gim­micks and rosy analy­ses to make the pro­pos­al add up and com­ply with the Sen­ate bud­get rules. The House’s bill fails to hew to cru­cial Sen­ate bud­get rules — mak­ing the pro­pos­al unten­able in the upper cham­ber. Mem­bers seem to be aware of this dilem­ma.

“My must-changes are I just want the math to work,” Rep. David Schweik­ert (R‑AZ) said of bring­ing the House and Sen­ate bills togeth­er.

The math solu­tions in the Sen­ate have proved polit­i­cal­ly dif­fi­cult.

The Sen­ate bill leaves many of the deduc­tions the House repeals untouched, and instead repeals Obamacare’s indi­vid­ual man­date, phas­es in the cor­po­rate tax cut, increas­es the child tax cred­it, ful­ly repeals the state and local tax deduc­tion, keeps the sev­en tax brack­ets — instead of the House’s four — and sun­sets almost all of the tax relief for indi­vid­ual Amer­i­cans by 2025.

By Wednes­day, one sen­a­tor, Ron John­son (R‑WI), had already come out against the Senate’s bill, say­ing it helped cor­po­ra­tions more than small busi­ness­es and fam­i­lies. Sev­er­al more cru­cial sen­a­tors have been tight-lipped about their feel­ings. A recent dis­tri­b­u­tion­al analy­sis from the Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion found that the Senate’s pro­pos­al, which sun­sets the indi­vid­ual tax reforms to pay for a cor­po­rate tax cut, would raise tax­es on the poor by 2021 and across the board in 2027.

Are cor­po­rate tax cuts enough to keep Repub­li­cans togeth­er? It’s start­ing to look like it.

There is one pol­i­cy that is uni­fy­ing the Repub­li­can ranks: They real­ly want to cut the cor­po­rate tax rate [9]. It’s the cen­ter­piece of every plan they have released in both the House and the Sen­ate, and they’ve spent weeks float­ing wild­ly unpop­u­lar ways to pay for it.

“It’s in all of our best inter­est to have these tax cuts for cor­po­ra­tions so that they will have more mon­ey to invest in their busi­ness and pay their work­ers,” Rep. Mike Conaway (R‑TX) told Vox.

Low­er­ing the cor­po­rate tax from its cur­rent 35 per­cent to 20 per­cent, as Repub­li­cans are propos­ing, is cost­ly — in the con­text of the cur­rent bill, the Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion [10] esti­mates it would cost $1.33 tril­lion over 10 years. Repub­li­cans argue that this cost will be par­tial­ly off­set through incred­i­ble eco­nom­ic growth — push­ing cor­po­ra­tions to invest more in their work­ers and bring more jobs back to the Unit­ed States. And most econ­o­mists believe that tem­po­rary cor­po­rate cuts do lit­tle or noth­ing to boost eco­nom­ic growth [11], because cor­po­ra­tions can’t count on the cuts in the future.

So even the most vul­ner­a­ble Repub­li­can law­mak­ers from states like New York, New Jer­sey, and Cal­i­for­nia that are adverse­ly impact­ed by both the House and Sen­ate pro­pos­als to pay for the per­ma­nent cor­po­rate tax cut are pri­or­i­tiz­ing doing so.

“Over­all there is much more sub­stan­tive tax pol­i­cy that is in agree­ment,” Rep. Tom Reed (R‑NY) said of the ide­ol­o­gy behind the Sen­ate and House bills, mak­ing a case for a per­ma­nent cor­po­rate tax cut. “From a growth per­spec­tive on the busi­ness side, the less you can rely on hav­ing a long-term plan­ning capa­bil­i­ty and mak­ing those invest­ments long term, I would say that has a lit­tle more neg­a­tive impact.”

Still, cor­po­rate rate cuts also have a lot of poten­tial to be polit­i­cal­ly expen­sive.

Six­ty per­cent of reg­is­tered vot­ers [12] think cor­po­ra­tions pay “too lit­tle” in tax­es, accord­ing to a Sep­tem­ber poll from Morn­ing Con­sult and Politi­co sur­vey­ing a lit­tle under 2,000 Amer­i­cans. A more recent [13] Morn­ing Consult/Politico sur­vey from Octo­ber found only 39 per­cent of Amer­i­cans think low­er­ing the cor­po­rate tax rate should be part of the tax plan — with 59 per­cent of Repub­li­can vot­ers sup­port­ing it. Anoth­er poll from Pew Research Cen­ter [14] showed that 53 per­cent of Repub­li­cans think cor­po­rate tax rates should either be raised or stay the same.

...
———-

“The House just passed its tax reform plan. It’s dras­ti­cal­ly dif­fer­ent from the Senate’s.” by Tara Gol­shan; Vox; 11/16/2017 [7]

Going into the vote, House lead­er­ship told law­mak­ers not to bash the Sen­ate tax bill — a move that has made some feel like the plan is to adopt a lot more of the Sen­ate bill. Already, some of the dif­fer­ences are mak­ing House Repub­li­cans grum­ble. The Sen­ate ful­ly repeals the state and local income and prop­er­ty tax deduc­tion, cuts health care, and sun­sets tax relief for indi­vid­ual Amer­i­cans in order to pay for cor­po­rate tax cuts.”

‘Don’t bash the bill we might have to vote for!’ That was the implied mes­sage from House GOP lead­ers fol­low­ing the pas­sage of the House­’s own bill. And that means a lot of the high­ly unpop­u­lar fea­tures of the Sen­ate’s ver­sion — like the full repeal of state and local tax­es deduc­tions and prop­er­ty tax deduc­tions — are prob­a­bly going to be things the House GOP­ers even­tu­al­ly have to vote for. Best not to bash the ideas you’re going to have to vote for:

...
There’s no ques­tion that Repub­li­cans have been grap­pling with a major math prob­lem with their tax bill, search­ing for bud­get gim­micks and rosy analy­ses to make the pro­pos­al add up and com­ply with the Sen­ate bud­get rules. The House’s bill fails to hew to cru­cial Sen­ate bud­get rules — mak­ing the pro­pos­al unten­able in the upper cham­ber. Mem­bers seem to be aware of this dilem­ma.

“My must-changes are I just want the math to work,” Rep. David Schweik­ert (R‑AZ) said of bring­ing the House and Sen­ate bills togeth­er.

The math solu­tions in the Sen­ate have proved polit­i­cal­ly dif­fi­cult.

The Sen­ate bill leaves many of the deduc­tions the House repeals untouched, and instead repeals Obamacare’s indi­vid­ual man­date, phas­es in the cor­po­rate tax cut, increas­es the child tax cred­it, ful­ly repeals the state and local tax deduc­tion, keeps the sev­en tax brack­ets — instead of the House’s four — and sun­sets almost all of the tax relief for indi­vid­ual Amer­i­cans by 2025.
...

Ful­ly repeal­ing state and local tax deduc­tions and prop­er­ty tax deduc­tions — some­thing that will ham­mer peo­ple liv­ing high­er-tax ‘Blue’ states where prop­er­ty val­ues also tend to be high­er — is some­thing that all GOP­ers in the House and Sen­ate are prob­a­bly going to end up hav­ing to vote for in order to pay for per­ma­nent cuts to the tax­es for the wealthy and cor­po­ra­tions. Includ­ing the GOP­ers from those Blue states that are about to get ham­mered. It’s not exact­ly great pol­i­tics.

And yet it appears that ‘Blue state’ and ‘Red state’ Repub­li­cans are large­ly unit­ed behind this tax cut push. Unit­ed by a desire to slash cor­po­rate tax­es, the cen­ter­piece of both bills:

...
Are cor­po­rate tax cuts enough to keep Repub­li­cans togeth­er? It’s start­ing to look like it.

There is one pol­i­cy that is uni­fy­ing the Repub­li­can ranks: They real­ly want to cut the cor­po­rate tax rate [9]. It’s the cen­ter­piece of every plan they have released in both the House and the Sen­ate, and they’ve spent weeks float­ing wild­ly unpop­u­lar ways to pay for it.

“It’s in all of our best inter­est to have these tax cuts for cor­po­ra­tions so that they will have more mon­ey to invest in their busi­ness and pay their work­ers,” Rep. Mike Conaway (R‑TX) told Vox.

Low­er­ing the cor­po­rate tax from its cur­rent 35 per­cent to 20 per­cent, as Repub­li­cans are propos­ing, is cost­ly — in the con­text of the cur­rent bill, the Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion [10] esti­mates it would cost $1.33 tril­lion over 10 years. Repub­li­cans argue that this cost will be par­tial­ly off­set through incred­i­ble eco­nom­ic growth — push­ing cor­po­ra­tions to invest more in their work­ers and bring more jobs back to the Unit­ed States. And most econ­o­mists believe that tem­po­rary cor­po­rate cuts do lit­tle or noth­ing to boost eco­nom­ic growth [11], because cor­po­ra­tions can’t count on the cuts in the future.

So even the most vul­ner­a­ble Repub­li­can law­mak­ers from states like New York, New Jer­sey, and Cal­i­for­nia that are adverse­ly impact­ed by both the House and Sen­ate pro­pos­als to pay for the per­ma­nent cor­po­rate tax cut are pri­or­i­tiz­ing doing so.

...

“There is one pol­i­cy that is uni­fy­ing the Repub­li­can ranks: They real­ly want to cut the cor­po­rate tax rate [9]. It’s the cen­ter­piece of every plan they have released in both the House and the Sen­ate, and they’ve spent weeks float­ing wild­ly unpop­u­lar ways to pay for it.”

Per­ma­nent­ly slash­ing cor­po­rate tax rates from 35 to 20 per­cent: It’s the one ele­ment that both the House and Sen­ate GOP­ers insist upon for any final ver­sion of the bill. The tax cuts for the wealthy or tax hikes on every­one else are up for the debate but those cor­po­rate tax rates of 20 per­cent must be there in in the final ver­sion. And it’s that uni­fied desire to deliv­ery cor­po­ra­tions this mas­sive tax good­ie that is guar­an­tee­ing so much pain else­where. Because as the fol­low­ing arti­cle notes, there is sim­ply no way to make this cor­po­rate tax cut pay for itself, even if you elim­i­nate every cor­po­rate tax loop­hole [15]:

Vox

The Repub­li­can tax plan’s orig­i­nal sin
A giant, unpop­u­lar, unwork­able busi­ness tax cut.

Updat­ed by Matthew Ygle­sias
Nov 6, 2017, 9:00am EST

Paul Ryan, speak­ing to CNN about the tax over­haul bill the passed ear­li­er this month, says “the whole pur­pose of this is a mid­dle-class tax cut.” That’s in line with the rhetoric Don­ald Trump deployed on the cam­paign trail, in line with pub­lic opin­ion polling about what vot­ers want, and reflects a kind of com­mon sense con­ser­vatism on eco­nom­ic pol­i­cy that says what typ­i­cal Amer­i­cans could most use from the gov­ern­ment is to keep more of their hard-earned cash rather than some big new gov­ern­ment pro­grams.

Ryan and his team have even cooked up a mod­el fam­i­ly — a mom, dad, and two kids get­ting by on the nation­al medi­an house­hold income — who stand to reap a wind­fall of $1,182 per year from the plan.

Unfor­tu­nate­ly for the Amer­i­can mid­dle class, Ryan is lying. The hypo­thet­i­cal fam­i­ly his top spokesper­son Ash­Lee Strong described would get a tax cut of almost $1,200 — for one year. It gets small­er in year two, small­er still in year three, small­er still in year four, and small­er still in year five. It near­ly van­ish­es in the sixth year of the Ryan tax plan, and in years sev­en, eight, nine, and 10 the fam­i­ly would be pay­ing high­er tax­es than under cur­rent law. That tax hike is not only per­ma­nent, it actu­al­ly grows over time because of a change to the infla­tion index­ing of tax brack­ets.

On aver­age, over the entire 10-year scor­ing win­dow, the fam­i­ly would get a total tax cut of $3,550. Yet over the same time peri­od, the nation­al debt would grow by $4,644 per per­son — or about $18,500 for a fam­i­ly of four.

There’s noth­ing wrong with run­ning a bud­get deficit if you’re accom­plish­ing some­thing worth­while. But to go $18,500 in debt in order to secure a $3,550 tax cut is pre­pos­ter­ous. And yet some­thing like that is an inevitable con­se­quence of the Repub­li­can tax plan’s orig­i­nal deci­sion — an unpop­u­lar and unwork­able scheme to reduce the cor­po­rate income tax rate from 35 per­cent to 20 per­cent.

Real cor­po­rate tax reform is a rea­son­able idea

The basic sto­ry with the cor­po­rate income tax in the Unit­ed States is that the statu­to­ry rate of 35 per­cent is one of the high­est of any rich coun­try, but there are so many cor­po­rate tax loop­holes that com­pa­nies on aver­age only actu­al­ly pay in the mid-to-high 20s.

Under the cir­cum­stances, there’s a strong case for cor­po­rate income tax reform. By elim­i­nat­ing a bunch of deduc­tions you should able to sig­nif­i­cant­ly reduce cor­po­rate tax rates with­out increas­ing the bud­get deficit. That would make the con­duct of busi­ness in the Unit­ed States both fair­er and more effi­cient by treat­ing all forms of busi­ness activ­i­ty more equal­ly. That, in turn, should pro­vide a mod­est boost to eco­nom­ic growth as well as elim­i­nat­ing some has­sles and wast­ed time in terms of tax com­pli­ance.

The Oba­ma admin­is­tra­tion looked at this and con­clud­ed that there was a rea­son­able reform path to cut­ting from 35 per­cent to 28 per­cent while rais­ing some rev­enue.

Mitt Romney’s pres­i­den­tial cam­paign in 2012 looked at it and con­clud­ed more aggres­sive­ly that there was a reform path to cut­ting from 35 per­cent to 25 per­cent while prob­a­bly los­ing some rev­enue.

Repub­li­cans copied a num­ber from anoth­er plan

But House Repub­li­cans looked at Romney’s plan and decid­ed to cut 5 per­cent­age points low­er — all the way down to 20 per­cent — even though there’s no way to make that work. Remem­ber, the effec­tive cor­po­rate income tax rate paid in the Unit­ed States is some­where in the high 20s, vary­ing a bit from year to year. Even if you closed every sin­gle deduc­tion you couldn’t get down to 20. And nobody real­ly wants to close every sin­gle deduc­tion any­way. So in the long run, the 20 per­cent tar­get sim­ply isn’t work­able with­out rais­ing tax­es on indi­vid­u­als — which is why Strong’s favorite family’s tax cut even­tu­al­ly goes away and becomes a tax hike.

...

A year ago, the peo­ple involved in draft­ing the plan were com­plete­ly aware of the math­e­mat­i­cal real­i­ties. That’s why they weren’t propos­ing a 20 per­cent cor­po­rate income tax rate. Instead, they pro­posed elim­i­nat­ing the cor­po­rate income tax as we know it alto­geth­er and replac­ing it instead with a des­ti­na­tion-based cash flow tax (DBCFT).

This was basi­cal­ly a broad 20 per­cent nation­al con­sump­tion tax — sim­i­lar to a retail sales tax except levied on ser­vices as well as goods — par­tial­ly off­set by a big pay­roll tax cut. The result, on net, would be a tax on con­sump­tion that was financed out of past sav­ings. This was an idea with some mer­it that end­ed up being derailed by pub­lic and con­gres­sion­al con­fu­sion about its bor­der adjust­ment pro­vi­sions, though I think it would have died any­way once mem­bers of Con­gress under­stood its impli­ca­tions for non-poor retirees. The key point, how­ev­er, is that the 20 per­cent DBCFT was not the same thing as a 20 per­cent cor­po­rate income tax.

Indeed, I assume that if Repub­li­cans had thought they were the same thing, they wouldn’t have gone through the trou­ble of invent­ing a whole new kind of tax! But hav­ing dropped the DBCFT idea, Repub­li­cans didn’t rethink the rest of their plan. They just copied the num­ber “20” over from one tax plan to anoth­er and tried to make the math work based on a 20 per­cent cor­po­rate income tax rate.

But the math doesn’t work. The busi­ness tax cuts in the GOP plan add $1 tril­lion to the deficit over 10 years, account­ing for two-thirds of the total net tax cut­ting. And with plen­ty of tax cuts for rich peo­ple also in the plan, that leaves Repub­li­cans rais­ing tax­es on many fam­i­lies and increas­ing the deficit.

Now they’re stuck with an unpop­u­lar, unwork­able night­mare

There are at least two big prob­lems with the approach House Repub­li­cans end­ed up tak­ing. One is that it’s ridicu­lous­ly unpop­u­lar. Only 24 per­cent of the pub­lic says we should have a cor­po­rate tax cut [18], and that’s with­out con­sid­er­ing any trade­offs.

A lot of the indi­vid­ual con­tentious mea­sures in the GOP plan are defen­si­ble in at least some con­texts. But to elim­i­nate a tax cred­it for adopt­ing a child while rais­ing tax­es on PhD pro­grams and cur­tail­ing the home­build­ing indus­try is a tough sell if the pur­pose of it all is to pass a big unpop­u­lar cor­po­rate tax cut.

But it gets worse. Even with a bunch of pop­u­lar tax breaks going away, and even with Strong’s sam­ple fam­i­ly even­tu­al­ly fac­ing a future of end­less­ly esca­lat­ing tax increas­es, the cor­po­rate tax cut is so huge that it blows a hole in the long-term bud­get deficit in a way that vio­lates Sen­ate rules. So the House bill not only has a pro­found­ly unpop­u­lar trade-off at its heart — it lit­er­al­ly can­not pass the Sen­ate with­out sub­stan­tial changes. Which means if they’re smart, House Repub­li­cans will stop and make some seri­ous changes of their own rather than just plow­ing ahead.

If.

———-

“The Repub­li­can tax plan’s orig­i­nal sin” by Matthew Ygle­sias; Vox; 11/06/2017 [15]

Unfor­tu­nate­ly for the Amer­i­can mid­dle class, Ryan is lying. The hypo­thet­i­cal fam­i­ly his top spokesper­son Ash­Lee Strong described would get a tax cut of almost $1,200 — for one year. It gets small­er in year two, small­er still in year three, small­er still in year four, and small­er still in year five. It near­ly van­ish­es in the sixth year of the Ryan tax plan, and in years sev­en, eight, nine, and 10 the fam­i­ly would be pay­ing high­er tax­es than under cur­rent law. That tax hike is not only per­ma­nent, it actu­al­ly grows over time because of a change to the infla­tion index­ing of tax brack­ets.”

Yep, House Speak­er Paul Ryan is bla­tant­ly lying when he claims that this tax cut bill is all about tax cuts for the Amer­i­can mid­dle-class. The way the House ver­sion works, the tax cuts start erod­ing after the first year, are near­ly com­plete­ly gone by year six, and tax­es rise for mid­dle-class fam­i­lies after year sev­en. And just keep on ris­ing. So that hypo­thet­i­cal mid­dle-class fam­i­ly of four will get a total tax cut of $3,550 (which expires), while the nation­al debt ris­es $4,644 per per­son (includ­ing the two kids in this fam­i­ly of four). It’s a giant scam. And it’s the kind of scam that is utter­ly unavoid­able giv­en the cor­po­rate tax cut:

...
On aver­age, over the entire 10-year scor­ing win­dow, the fam­i­ly would get a total tax cut of $3,550. Yet over the same time peri­od, the nation­al debt would grow by $4,644 per per­son — or about $18,500 for a fam­i­ly of four.

There’s noth­ing wrong with run­ning a bud­get deficit if you’re accom­plish­ing some­thing worth­while. But to go $18,500 in debt in order to secure a $3,550 tax cut is pre­pos­ter­ous. And yet some­thing like that is an inevitable con­se­quence of the Repub­li­can tax plan’s orig­i­nal deci­sion — an unpop­u­lar and unwork­able scheme to reduce the cor­po­rate income tax rate from 35 per­cent to 20 per­cent.
...

“There’s noth­ing wrong with run­ning a bud­get deficit if you’re accom­plish­ing some­thing worth­while. But to go $18,500 in debt in order to secure a $3,550 tax cut is pre­pos­ter­ous. And yet some­thing like that is an inevitable con­se­quence of the Repub­li­can tax plan’s orig­i­nal deci­sion — an unpop­u­lar and unwork­able scheme to reduce the cor­po­rate income tax rate from 35 per­cent to 20 per­cent.

And notice how it would have been pos­si­ble for the GOP to cut cor­po­rate tax­es pret­ty sig­nif­i­cant­ly with­out requir­ing these stealth mid­dle-class tax hikes sim­ply by clos­ing cor­po­rate tax loop­holes. Mitt Rom­ney only pro­posed a cut to 25 per­cent dur­ing his 2012 elec­tion and even the Oba­ma admin­is­tra­tion con­clud­ed that cor­po­rate tax­es could have dropped from 35 to 28 per­cent with­out any drop of tax rev­enues sim­ply by clos­ing loop­holes. But the GOP now feels com­pelled to drop it all the to 20 per­cent instead, hence the need for those mid­dle-class tax hikes:

...
Under the cir­cum­stances, there’s a strong case for cor­po­rate income tax reform. By elim­i­nat­ing a bunch of deduc­tions you should able to sig­nif­i­cant­ly reduce cor­po­rate tax rates with­out increas­ing the bud­get deficit. That would make the con­duct of busi­ness in the Unit­ed States both fair­er and more effi­cient by treat­ing all forms of busi­ness activ­i­ty more equal­ly. That, in turn, should pro­vide a mod­est boost to eco­nom­ic growth as well as elim­i­nat­ing some has­sles and wast­ed time in terms of tax com­pli­ance.

The Oba­ma admin­is­tra­tion looked at this and con­clud­ed that there was a rea­son­able reform path to cut­ting from 35 per­cent to 28 per­cent while rais­ing some rev­enue.

Mitt Romney’s pres­i­den­tial cam­paign in 2012 looked at it and con­clud­ed more aggres­sive­ly that there was a reform path to cut­ting from 35 per­cent to 25 per­cent while prob­a­bly los­ing some rev­enue.

Repub­li­cans copied a num­ber from anoth­er plan

But House Repub­li­cans looked at Romney’s plan and decid­ed to cut 5 per­cent­age points low­er — all the way down to 20 per­cent — even though there’s no way to make that work. Remem­ber, the effec­tive cor­po­rate income tax rate paid in the Unit­ed States is some­where in the high 20s, vary­ing a bit from year to year. Even if you closed every sin­gle deduc­tion you couldn’t get down to 20. And nobody real­ly wants to close every sin­gle deduc­tion any­way. So in the long run, the 20 per­cent tar­get sim­ply isn’t work­able with­out rais­ing tax­es on indi­vid­u­als — which is why Strong’s favorite family’s tax cut even­tu­al­ly goes away and becomes a tax hike.
...

“But House Repub­li­cans looked at Romney’s plan and decid­ed to cut 5 per­cent­age points low­er — all the way down to 20 per­cent — even though there’s no way to make that work. Remem­ber, the effec­tive cor­po­rate income tax rate paid in the Unit­ed States is some­where in the high 20s, vary­ing a bit from year to year. Even if you closed every sin­gle deduc­tion you couldn’t get down to 20. And nobody real­ly wants to close every sin­gle deduc­tion any­way. So in the long run, the 20 per­cent tar­get sim­ply isn’t work­able with­out rais­ing tax­es on indi­vid­u­als — which is why Strong’s favorite family’s tax cut even­tu­al­ly goes away and becomes a tax hike.”

And even with those mid­dle-class tax cuts, the cost of the cor­po­rate tax cuts still aren’t cov­ered. Hence the House ver­sion’s deficit explo­sion, a vio­la­tion of the Sen­ate Byrd rule:

...
But it gets worse. Even with a bunch of pop­u­lar tax breaks going away, and even with Strong’s sam­ple fam­i­ly even­tu­al­ly fac­ing a future of end­less­ly esca­lat­ing tax increas­es, the cor­po­rate tax cut is so huge that it blows a hole in the long-term bud­get deficit in a way that vio­lates Sen­ate rules. So the House bill not only has a pro­found­ly unpop­u­lar trade-off at its heart — it lit­er­al­ly can­not pass the Sen­ate with­out sub­stan­tial changes. Which means if they’re smart, House Repub­li­cans will stop and make some seri­ous changes of their own rather than just plow­ing ahead.
...

And that gives a bet­ter idea of just how polit­i­cal­ly awful the Sen­ate ver­sion of the tax bill is: the deficit explodes even with the House ver­sion’s tax hike in the mid­dle-class, vio­lat­ing the Byrd rule. The Sen­ate address­es fis­cal hole this by extract­ing even more mon­ey from the poor and mid­dle-class.

The Sequester Cuts. Includ­ing Medicare Cuts

And there’s the Medicare cuts. Yep, even though Medicare cuts aren’t men­tioned any­one in the House or Sen­ate ver­sions of the tax bill, Medicare will still face a $25 bil­lion cut. Why? Because of spe­cial “sequester” rules the Tea Par­ty con­ser­v­a­tives man­dat­ed dur­ing the 2010 bud­get show­down that forces across-the-board cuts to fed­er­al pro­grams when­ev­er Con­gress pass­es a bill that increas­es the deficit. And while Med­ic­aid, Social Secu­ri­ty, and food stamps are pro­tect­ed from the sequester, Medicare isn’t. So of the ~$136 bil­lion in sequester cuts that the House tax bill will force on fed­er­al gov­ern­ment pro­grams in 2018 alone, $25 bil­lion of that will come from cuts in Medicare [19]:

Talk­ing Points Memo

House GOP’s Tax Bill Would Trig­ger A $25 Bil­lion Cut To Medicare

By Alice Oll­stein
Pub­lished Novem­ber 17, 2017 6:00 am

Two weeks after its intro­duc­tion and fol­low­ing zero hear­ings, the House of Rep­re­sen­ta­tives passed an approx­i­mate­ly $1.5 tril­lion dol­lar tax cut on Thurs­day. Most of the focus has been on the bill’s tax ben­e­fits for the wealthy and cor­po­ra­tions, but some law­mak­ers are sound­ing the alarm that pas­sage of the bill will also trig­ger an esti­mat­ed $25 bil­lion cut [20] to Medicare.

With the Sen­ate expect­ed to take up its own bill after the Thanks­giv­ing recess, Democ­rats strug­gling to mount an oppo­si­tion to the bill see an open­ing in its con­tro­ver­sial health care impacts—including the Medicare cuts, the repeal of Obamacare’s indi­vid­ual man­date [21], and the elim­i­na­tion of the med­ical expens­es deduc­tion in the House bill.

The Medicare cut—announced [20] by the non-par­ti­san Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office on Tuesday—can only be waived [22] by a major­i­ty of the House and a 60-vote super­ma­jor­i­ty of the Sen­ate.

Thanks to laws cre­at­ed by the Tea Party’s infa­mous 2010 sequester show­down over gov­ern­ment spend­ing, auto­mat­ic cuts spring into action any­time Con­gress pass­es a bill that bal­loons the fed­er­al deficit, as the tax bill would. The approx­i­mate­ly $136 bil­lion in cuts spurred by the GOP tax bill would hit a num­ber of gov­ern­ment programs—including farm sub­si­dies and the Bor­der Patrol [23]—but would cut most deeply into Medicare. Med­ic­aid, Social Secu­ri­ty, and food stamps are pro­tect­ed.

These cuts would vio­late Pres­i­dent Trump’s repeat­ed cam­paign promis­es [24] not to touch Medicare and oth­er social safe­ty net pro­grams. But for House Speak­er Paul Ryan (R‑WI) and oth­er law­mak­ers who have for decades longed for an oppor­tu­ni­ty to cut to Medicare and oth­er fed­er­al ben­e­fits, the cuts would be a fea­ture rather than a bug.

The CBO’s announce­ment this week has also raised the hack­les of the influ­en­tial AARP, who wrote to Con­gress on behalf of their 38 mil­lion mem­bers in oppo­si­tion to the bill.

“The large increase in the deficit will inevitably lead to calls for greater spend­ing cuts, which are like­ly to include dra­mat­ic cuts to Medicare, Med­ic­aid and oth­er crit­i­cal pro­grams serv­ing old­er Amer­i­cans,” they warned. “The Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office has now pub­lished a let­ter stat­ing that unless Con­gress takes action, H.R. 1 will result in auto­mat­ic fed­er­al fund­ing cuts of $136 bil­lion in fis­cal year 2018, $25 bil­lion of which must come from Medicare.”

Con­gress could avoid these cuts by waiv­ing the so-called “pay-as-you-go” rules, but it’s unclear whether Repub­li­cans or Democ­rats would see that as being in their polit­i­cal inter­est. Sen­a­tors from both par­ties would have to sup­port the waiv­er to see it pass the upper cham­ber. Repub­li­cans who reg­u­lar­ly rail against run­away gov­ern­ment spend­ing may not want to vote against the cuts, and Democ­rats have sug­gest­ed [23] they have lit­tle inter­est in bail­ing out Repub­li­cans’ deficit-bust­ing tax bill.

Yet some, includ­ing Sen. Chris Van Hollen (D‑MD), are already sound­ing the alarm. In a let­ter [25] to the House Free­dom Cau­cus on Thurs­day, he demand­ed to know if they would vote to waive the bud­get rules if the tax bill became law.

...

———-

“House GOP’s Tax Bill Would Trig­ger A $25 Bil­lion Cut To Medicare” by Alice Oll­stein; Talk­ing Points Memo; 11/17/2017 [19]

“Thanks to laws cre­at­ed by the Tea Party’s infa­mous 2010 sequester show­down over gov­ern­ment spend­ing, auto­mat­ic cuts spring into action any­time Con­gress pass­es a bill that bal­loons the fed­er­al deficit, as the tax bill would. The approx­i­mate­ly $136 bil­lion in cuts spurred by the GOP tax bill would hit a num­ber of gov­ern­ment programs—including farm sub­si­dies and the Bor­der Patrol [23]—but would cut most deeply into Medicare. Med­ic­aid, Social Secu­ri­ty, and food stamps are pro­tect­ed.”

In case it was­n’t com­plete­ly obvi­ous that this tax cut would lead direct­ly to cuts in fed­er­al pro­grams, the sequester is a good reminder of this because it’s lit­er­al­ly a rule that man­dates cuts to fed­er­al pro­grams when Con­gress increas­es the deficit. Fed­er­al cuts aren’t an option unless the sequester is end­ed.

And let’s not for­get that, while Pres­i­dent Trump pledged to leave Medicare untouched dur­ing his cam­paign, gut­ting Medicare is a long-term dream for the GOP at large:

...
These cuts would vio­late Pres­i­dent Trump’s repeat­ed cam­paign promis­es [24] not to touch Medicare and oth­er social safe­ty net pro­grams. But for House Speak­er Paul Ryan (R‑WI) and oth­er law­mak­ers who have for decades longed for an oppor­tu­ni­ty to cut to Medicare and oth­er fed­er­al ben­e­fits, the cuts would be a fea­ture rather than a bug
...

So it’s look­ing very pos­si­ble that Paul Ryan’s dream of cut­ting Medicare is about to hap­pen. Soon. Because that $25 bil­lion cut will be man­dat­ed to hap­pen in 2018:

...
The CBO’s announce­ment this week has also raised the hack­les of the influ­en­tial AARP, who wrote to Con­gress on behalf of their 38 mil­lion mem­bers in oppo­si­tion to the bill.

“The large increase in the deficit will inevitably lead to calls for greater spend­ing cuts, which are like­ly to include dra­mat­ic cuts to Medicare, Med­ic­aid and oth­er crit­i­cal pro­grams serv­ing old­er Amer­i­cans,” they warned. “The Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office has now pub­lished a let­ter stat­ing that unless Con­gress takes action, H.R. 1 will result in auto­mat­ic fed­er­al fund­ing cuts of $136 bil­lion in fis­cal year 2018, $25 bil­lion of which must come from Medicare.”
...

Also note that the cuts to Medicare are capped at 4 per­cent per year, which comes out to $25 bil­lion. So if the sequester man­dates that Medicare should be cut even more than $25 bil­lion, those addi­tion­al cuts are going to have to come from else­where in the fed­er­al bud­get [26]. In oth­er words, these tax cuts for cor­po­ra­tions and the rich aren’t just being paid for with high­er tax­es on the poor and mid­dle-class. All ben­e­fi­cia­ries of fed­er­al spend­ing are also going to expe­ri­ence a cut.

And the only way to avoid these cuts will be for the GOP to repeal the sequester, which would be pret­ty remark­able if it hap­pened when you con­sid­er that the sequester was demand­ed by the GOP over fears of ris­ing nation­al debt.

Is it a Tax Hike on the Poor, or a Pre­mi­um Hike for the Poor’s Health Insur­ance? How About Both

Of course, since the the $25 bil­lion annu­al cut to Medicare and the rest of the seques­tra­tion cuts trig­gered by the House­’s ver­sion of the tax cut are trig­gered due to the explo­sion in the fed­er­al deficit, the sequester cuts might not be quite as large for the Sen­ate ver­sion sim­ply because the Sen­ate ver­sion has to fol­low the Byrd rule and isn’t allowed to blow up the deficit quite as much. But as we already saw, it’s not like health care will go untouched under the Sen­ate’s ver­sion thanks to the repeal of the Oba­macare man­date.

And as we’ll see below, that Oba­macare man­date repeal result in a pret­ty remark­able esti­mate for the impact of the Sen­ate’s tax bill on the poor­est Amer­i­cans: the Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion (JTC) — the con­gres­sion­al com­mit­tee con­sist­ing of House and Sen­ate mem­bers tasked with esti­mat­ing the costs of pro­posed leg­is­la­tion — esti­mat­ed the tax bill for the poor­est Amer­i­cans would rise over 25 per­cent by 2027! And this spike in tax­es for the poor was large­ly due to the repeal of the Oba­macare man­date.

Now, as we’ll also see, that 25 per­cent rise in the tax bur­den for the poor is based on the fact that the gov­ern­ment won’t be pay­ing health insur­ance sub­si­dies to 13 mil­lion Amer­i­cans who assumed to drop their health insur­ance cov­er­age if the man­date is repealed. So it’s the loss of health insur­ance sub­si­dies that’s dri­ving the 25 per­cent spike in the tax bur­den for the poor, a fact that the GOP is angri­ly latch­ing onto to in this debate to make it look like this tax bill isn’t pred­i­cat­ed on the poor pay­ing the bill for the wealthy’s tax cuts. And yet it’s hard to ignore the real­i­ty that the Sen­ate’s tax bill is pay­ing for itself by assum­ing that the fed­er­al gov­ern­ment spends a lot less mon­ey on health care for the poor, which sure looks a lot like the poor pay­ing for tax cuts for the rich [27]:

The Hill

Tax cuts in Sen­ate bill would evap­o­rate in a decade: JCT

By Niv Elis and Peter Sul­li­van — 11/16/17 10:40 AM EST

Tax cuts for indi­vid­u­als in the Senate’s lat­est tax plan would dis­ap­pear by 2027, accord­ing to an analy­sis by the Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion (JCT), with some even see­ing a tax increase.

While tax­pay­ers would see their tax bills drop by 7.4 per­cent on aver­age in 2019 under the bill, by 2027, their tax­es would rise by an aver­age of 0.2 per­cent.

The poor would be hard­est hit, with those mak­ing between $20,000 and $30,000 see­ing their tax bills rise start­ing in 2021. By 2027, they would see a 25.4 per­cent increase in their tax bill.

Those mak­ing over $75,000 would still see their tax­es go down, albeit by less than 1 per­cent by the final year, while every­one mak­ing under $75,000 would see some lev­el of tax increase.

The drop-off is like­ly attrib­ut­able to a series of expir­ing tax cuts intro­duced in Finance Com­mit­tee Chair­man Orrin Hatch’s (R‑Utah) lat­est update to the bill. The leg­is­la­tion would also elim­i­nate the indi­vid­ual man­date for Oba­maCare and low­er some indi­vid­ual tax rates.

The JCT analy­sis looked at aver­ages for each income group and did not break out how many peo­ple at each lev­el would see their tax­es go up or down.

Hatch said that the sharp tax increase on low-income fam­i­lies found by the analy­sis was the result of the indi­vid­ual man­date being repealed. With­out the man­date, mil­lions of peo­ple are expect­ed to go with­out health insur­ance.

“JCT began with an assump­tion that some peo­ple in the low­er income brack­ets will opt to not pur­chase health insur­ance and thus not take advan­tage of avail­able tax cred­it sub­si­dies. With­out those cred­its, they see an over­all uptick in their tax lia­bil­i­ty,” Hatch said at the open­ing of Thursday’s finance com­mit­tee markup of the tax bill.

Low-income peo­ple would retain the option of access­ing those sub­si­dies if they chose to buy health insur­ance, he added. The JCT sim­ply reflect­ed the assump­tion that many would choose not to.

“Obvi­ous­ly, we have no inten­tion of rais­ing tax­es on these fam­i­lies,” he added.

Repub­li­can sen­a­tors at Thurs­day’s markup gen­er­al­ly agreed that the num­bers reflect­ed few­er peo­ple receiv­ing Oba­maCare sub­si­dies, which take the form of tax cred­its, when the indi­vid­ual man­date is removed.

...
———-

“Tax cuts in Sen­ate bill would evap­o­rate in a decade: JCT” by Niv Elis and Peter Sul­li­van; The Hill; 11/16/2017 [27]

“The poor would be hard­est hit, with those mak­ing between $20,000 and $30,000 see­ing their tax bills rise start­ing in 2021. By 2027, they would see a 25.4 per­cent increase in their tax bill.”

A 25 per­cent increase in tax­es for the poor in the GOP’s big tax cut bill. It’s not a great look.

But as the GOP tries to explain, this 25 per­cent increase is more or less vol­un­tary because the poor can still access sub­si­dized health insur­ance (thanks to the GOP’s repeat­ed fail­ures to repeal Oba­macare this year):

...
Hatch said that the sharp tax increase on low-income fam­i­lies found by the analy­sis was the result of the indi­vid­ual man­date being repealed. With­out the man­date, mil­lions of peo­ple are expect­ed to go with­out health insur­ance.

“JCT began with an assump­tion that some peo­ple in the low­er income brack­ets will opt to not pur­chase health insur­ance and thus not take advan­tage of avail­able tax cred­it sub­si­dies. With­out those cred­its, they see an over­all uptick in their tax lia­bil­i­ty,” Hatch said at the open­ing of Thursday’s finance com­mit­tee markup of the tax bill.

Low-income peo­ple would retain the option of access­ing those sub­si­dies if they chose to buy health insur­ance, he added. The JCT sim­ply reflect­ed the assump­tion that many would choose not to.

“Obvi­ous­ly, we have no inten­tion of rais­ing tax­es on these fam­i­lies,” he added.
...

And while it’s true that the peo­ple who decide to for­go health insur­ance once the man­date is repealed would be doing this vol­un­tar­i­ly, that ignores one of the more sig­nif­i­cant indi­rect effects of the man­date repeal: the 13 mil­lion peo­ple expect­ed to go with­out health insur­ance if the man­date is repealed are also expect­ed to be rel­a­tive­ly young and healthy peo­ple. And when you encour­age 13 mil­lion young and healthy peo­ple to drop out of the indi­vid­ual insur­ance mar­kets, you’re inevitably going to see a spike in pre­mi­ums.

And that’s the Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office (CBO) pro­ject­ed if that Oba­macare man­date is repealed: a 10 per­cent hike in pre­mi­ums for the indi­vid­ual health insur­ance mar­ket most years [28]:

Bloomberg Pol­i­tics

The Sen­ate Tax Bill’s Chances Just Got Bet­ter

By Steven T. Den­nis and Sahil Kapur
Novem­ber 22, 2017, 7:47 AM CST Updat­ed on Novem­ber 22, 2017, 10:03 AM CST

* Murkows­ki agrees to kill Obamacare’s indi­vid­ual man­date
* Hur­dles remain, includ­ing con­cerns about deficit effects

Alas­ka Sen­a­tor Lisa Murkowski’s deci­sion to agree to smash Obamacare’s indi­vid­ual man­date may remove one obsta­cle to pass­ing the Sen­ate Repub­li­can tax bill next week.

“I believe that the fed­er­al gov­ern­ment should not force any­one to buy some­thing they do not wish to buy in order to avoid being taxed,” she wrote in an op-ed in Alaska’s Dai­ly News-Min­er news­pa­per [29] post­ed online Tues­day.

Murkows­ki didn’t men­tion the tax bill in the arti­cle. But she pre­vi­ous­ly said she pre­ferred not to mix it with health care, and she was one of three mav­er­icks who killed the GOP’s Oba­macare repeal efforts ear­li­er this year.

Her announce­ment came after she said last week that Con­gress should act to sta­bi­lize health-insur­ance mar­kets in con­junc­tion with elim­i­nat­ing the indi­vid­ual man­date — a require­ment that indi­vid­u­als get health insur­ance or pay a fed­er­al penal­ty — in the tax leg­is­la­tion. In the op-ed, Murkows­ki reit­er­at­ed her sup­port for pro­posed leg­is­la­tion to do just that but didn’t indi­cate it was a pre­con­di­tion [30] for her to sup­port the tax bill.

The man­date repeal now appears much more like­ly to stay in the tax bill, where it helps off­set more than $300 bil­lion in oth­er tax cuts — rev­enue need­ed to bring the bill into com­pli­ance with Sen­ate bud­get rules. It’s also cru­cial to Pres­i­dent Don­ald Trump’s goal of mak­ing cor­po­rate tax cuts per­ma­nent under those rules.

There are still oth­er hur­dles for the tax bill to get to 50 votes. Repub­li­can Sen­a­tors John McCain of Ari­zona and Susan Collins of Maine — who joined Murkows­ki in tor­pe­do­ing efforts to repeal the Afford­able Care Act ear­li­er this year — have yet to sign on. And Wis­con­sin Sen­a­tor Ron John­son also threat­ened to vote against the bill with­out more tax relief for part­ner­ships, lim­it­ed lia­bil­i­ty com­pa­nies and oth­er so-called pass-through busi­ness­es. Sen­ate lead­ers have said they’re try­ing to address Johnson’s con­cerns.

Deficit Ques­tions

Three Repub­li­can sen­a­tors, Bob Cork­er of Ten­nessee, Jeff Flake of Ari­zona and James Lank­ford of Okla­homa, have raised spe­cif­ic con­cerns about the bill’s effect on the deficit. On Wednes­day, a new inde­pen­dent analy­sis of the bill found that it would con­tin­ue to reduce fed­er­al rev­enue each year after 2027 — a poten­tial com­pli­ca­tion for Sen­ate tax writ­ers.

Murkowski’s vote has long been wooed by the Sen­ate Major­i­ty Leader Mitch McConnell. The bill notably includes a pro­vi­sion open­ing up Alaska’s Arc­tic Nation­al Wildlife Refuge to oil drilling — a pri­or­i­ty for Alas­ka law­mak­ers for decades.

In recent weeks, Murkows­ki has been open­ly con­flict­ed on how to vote on the man­date, say­ing she was con­cerned that high­er pre­mi­ums from repeal­ing it could can­cel out the tax cuts for some in the mid­dle class. But in her op-ed, she drops those con­cerns, say­ing repeal­ing the man­date would sim­ply restore people’s free­dom to choose and not­ing the sky-high insur­ance costs under the ACA in her state.

“A sil­ver plan for a fam­i­ly of four, with a $9,000 deductible, will cost about $2,160 per month in 2018,” she wrote. For fam­i­lies who make too much for sub­si­dies, that amounts to near­ly $35,000 out of pock­et before insur­ance kicks in, she added.

Insur­ance-Mar­ket Effect

She said in the op-ed that she still wants Con­gress to pass bipar­ti­san leg­is­la­tion that aims to fix Oba­macare “as fast as pos­si­ble to sta­bi­lize our mar­kets.”

Leg­isla­tive staff mem­bers for Sen­a­tor Pat­ty Mur­ray, a Wash­ing­ton Demo­c­rat who joined Ten­nessee Repub­li­can Lamar Alexan­der to spon­sor a sta­bi­liza­tion bill, said in a memo Tues­day that the leg­is­la­tion wouldn’t be enough to pro­tect the sys­tem if the indi­vid­ual man­date is repealed.

“Repub­li­cans are seri­ous­ly mis­tak­en if they think pass­ing Alexan­der-Mur­ray will lessen the blow of repeal­ing the cov­er­age require­ment includ­ed in the Afford­able Care Act,” the memo said.

The Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office has esti­mat­ed that the $300 bil­lion in sav­ings from repeal­ing the man­date would come from about 13 mil­lion Amer­i­cans drop­ping their cov­er­age by 2027 — elim­i­nat­ing the need for fed­er­al sub­si­dies that help them afford it. Because many of them would be younger, health­i­er peo­ple, insur­ance pre­mi­ums would rise 10 per­cent in most years, the non­par­ti­san fis­cal score­keep­er found.

On Tues­day, a nation­al actu­ar­ies’ group said in a let­ter [31] to Sen­ate lead­ers that repeal­ing the indi­vid­ual man­date would raise costs for con­sumers and harm insur­ance mar­kets.

Fis­cal Study

Apart from health-care con­cerns, sen­a­tors will have to grap­ple with the bill’s long-term effects on fed­er­al deficits. A new study released Wednes­day may spell poten­tial trou­ble on that score.

A report from the Penn Whar­ton Bud­get Mod­el at the Uni­ver­si­ty of Penn­syl­va­nia found that the bill would reduce fed­er­al rev­enue in each year between 2027 and 2033. That find­ing would mean the bill doesn’t com­ply with a key bud­get rule that Sen­ate Repub­li­can lead­ers want to use to pass the leg­is­la­tion with a sim­ple major­i­ty over Democ­rats’ objec­tions.

The rule holds that any bills approved via the fast-track process that GOP lead­ers intend can­not add to the deficit out­side a 10-year bud­get win­dow.

The offi­cial score­keep­er, Congress’s Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion, has already found that the bill would gen­er­ate a sur­plus in its 10th year due to expir­ing tax breaks for busi­ness­es and indi­vid­u­als. But JCT hasn’t pub­licly weighed in on the rev­enue effects in sub­se­quent years.

...

———-

“The Sen­ate Tax Bill’s Chances Just Got Bet­ter” by Steven T. Den­nis and Sahil Kapur; Bloomberg Pol­i­tics; 11/22/2017 [28]

“The Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office has esti­mat­ed that the $300 bil­lion in sav­ings from repeal­ing the man­date would come from about 13 mil­lion Amer­i­cans drop­ping their cov­er­age by 2027 — elim­i­nat­ing the need for fed­er­al sub­si­dies that help them afford it. Because many of them would be younger, health­i­er peo­ple, insur­ance pre­mi­ums would rise 10 per­cent in most years, the non­par­ti­san fis­cal score­keep­er found.

So the Sen­ate’s tax plan does­n’t just involve rais­ing $300 bil­lion — to be spent on tax cuts for cor­po­ra­tions and the wealthy — by drop­ping 13 mil­lion most­ly young and healthy Amer­i­cans off of fed­er­al­ly sub­si­dized health insur­ance. It’s also a plan to desta­bi­lize the indi­vid­ual health insur­ance mar­kets because that’s what hap­pens when you do some­thing that’s expect­ed to suck the young and healthy out of the insur­ance mar­kets:

...
In recent weeks, Murkows­ki has been open­ly con­flict­ed on how to vote on the man­date, say­ing she was con­cerned that high­er pre­mi­ums from repeal­ing it could can­cel out the tax cuts for some in the mid­dle class. But in her op-ed, she drops those con­cerns, say­ing repeal­ing the man­date would sim­ply restore people’s free­dom to choose and not­ing the sky-high insur­ance costs under the ACA in her state.
...

It’s a remind that the sub­si­dies for the young and healthy to buy insur­ance weren’t sim­ply sub­si­dies for those indi­vid­u­als who choose to buy sub­si­dized insur­ance. They were sub­si­dies for every­one in the indi­vid­ual insur­ance mar­kets because hav­ing the young and healthy in those mar­kets help bring down rates for every­one.

It’s that dynam­ic of low­er cov­er­age lead­ing to high­er pre­mi­ums that’s led Lisa Murkows­ki, Alaska’s mod­er­ate GOP sen­a­tor, to open­ly fret about the impact of repeal­ing the man­date. And yet it sounds like she’s sud­den­ly decid­ed that repeal­ing the Oba­macare man­date is a great idea. Because it will enhance free­dom (appar­ent­ly the light fine for not get­ting health insur­ance harmed Amer­i­cans’ free­dom). And giv­en that Murkows­ki is one of a hand­ful of GOP Sen­a­tor’s to express con­cerns about the Sen­ate ver­sion of the tax bill, so hear her sud­den­ly come around to repeal­ing the man­date is a very omi­nous sign:

...
Alas­ka Sen­a­tor Lisa Murkowski’s deci­sion to agree to smash Obamacare’s indi­vid­ual man­date may remove one obsta­cle to pass­ing the Sen­ate Repub­li­can tax bill next week.

“I believe that the fed­er­al gov­ern­ment should not force any­one to buy some­thing they do not wish to buy in order to avoid being taxed,” she wrote in an op-ed in Alaska’s Dai­ly News-Min­er news­pa­per [29] post­ed online Tues­day.

Murkows­ki didn’t men­tion the tax bill in the arti­cle. But she pre­vi­ous­ly said she pre­ferred not to mix it with health care, and she was one of three mav­er­icks who killed the GOP’s Oba­macare repeal efforts ear­li­er this year.

...

Murkowski’s vote has long been wooed by the Sen­ate Major­i­ty Leader Mitch McConnell. The bill notably includes a pro­vi­sion open­ing up Alaska’s Arc­tic Nation­al Wildlife Refuge to oil drilling — a pri­or­i­ty for Alas­ka law­mak­ers for decades.

In recent weeks, Murkows­ki has been open­ly con­flict­ed on how to vote on the man­date, say­ing she was con­cerned that high­er pre­mi­ums from repeal­ing it could can­cel out the tax cuts for some in the mid­dle class. But in her op-ed, she drops those con­cerns, say­ing repeal­ing the man­date would sim­ply restore people’s free­dom to choose and not­ing the sky-high insur­ance costs under the ACA in her state.
...

“In recent weeks, Murkows­ki has been open­ly con­flict­ed on how to vote on the man­date, say­ing she was con­cerned that high­er pre­mi­ums from repeal­ing it could can­cel out the tax cuts for some in the mid­dle class. But in her op-ed, she drops those con­cerns, say­ing repeal­ing the man­date would sim­ply restore people’s free­dom to choose and not­ing the sky-high insur­ance costs under the ACA in her state.”

And there we have it: Sen­a­tor Murkows­ki notes the high insur­ance costs for Oba­macare in her state in her state­ment sup­port­ing the repeal of the man­date, a move that she has pre­vi­ous­ly been con­cerned with lead to high­er insur­ance costs.

So now the chances of the tax cut bill actu­al­ly pass­ing in the Sen­ate are A LOT high­er than they would have been with­out Murkowski’s sup­port. But there was one rather sig­nif­i­cant recent set back for the bill: Accord­ing to a study by the Whar­ton school at the Uni­ver­si­ty of Penn­syl­va­nia, despite all the tax hikes on the mid­dle-class and poor, the Sen­ate tax bill still vio­lates the Byrd rule:

...
Apart from health-care con­cerns, sen­a­tors will have to grap­ple with the bill’s long-term effects on fed­er­al deficits. A new study released Wednes­day may spell poten­tial trou­ble on that score.

A report from the Penn Whar­ton Bud­get Mod­el at the Uni­ver­si­ty of Penn­syl­va­nia found that the bill would reduce fed­er­al rev­enue in each year between 2027 and 2033. That find­ing would mean the bill doesn’t com­ply with a key bud­get rule that Sen­ate Repub­li­can lead­ers want to use to pass the leg­is­la­tion with a sim­ple major­i­ty over Democ­rats’ objec­tions.

The rule holds that any bills approved via the fast-track process that GOP lead­ers intend can­not add to the deficit out­side a 10-year bud­get win­dow.
...

But that’s still just an inde­pen­dent report. It’s going to be up to the con­gress­es’ offi­cial score­keep­er, the Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion (JTC), to make the deter­mi­na­tion as to whether or not the Sen­ate bill real­ly does pass the Byrd rule. And the JTC has yet to weigh in on that:

...
The offi­cial score­keep­er, Congress’s Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion, has already found that the bill would gen­er­ate a sur­plus in its 10th year due to expir­ing tax breaks for busi­ness­es and indi­vid­u­als. But JCT hasn’t pub­licly weighed in on the rev­enue effects in sub­se­quent years.
...

So while we don’t yet know what the JCT will decide, we do know that out­side ana­lysts don’t see the Sen­ate’s ver­sion of the bill ful­fill­ing the Byrd rule.

GOP Scheme to Trick­le Its Way Into Byrd Rule Com­pli­ance

And that skep­ti­cism over the Sen­ate bil­l’s com­pli­ance with the Byrd rule isn’t lim­it­ed to Uni­ver­si­ty of Penn­syl­va­nia analy­sis. The Tax Pol­i­cy Cen­ter recent­ly put out its own analy­sis on the Sen­ate bill. And that analy­sis assumed the tax cuts would indeed boost the over­all eco­nom­ic growth. In oth­er words, the analy­sis assumed the tax cuts for the rich and cor­po­ra­tions would pay for them­selves by boost­ing eco­nom­ic growth, a cen­tral tenet to the GOP’s tax-cut­ting ortho­doxy. But even with that enhanced growth, the analy­sis found that the still did­n’t pass the Byrd rule [32]:

Talk­ing Points Memo
DC

Study: Even With Dynam­ic Scor­ing, GOP Tax Bill Still Blows Up The Deficit

By Alice Oll­stein Pub­lished Novem­ber 20, 2017 2:52 pm

On Mon­day, the Tax Pol­i­cy Cen­ter released a new analy­sis [33] of the House tax bill that dis­proves claims [34] from GOP lead­er­ship and the Trump admin­is­tra­tion that the deep tax cuts for cor­po­ra­tions and the wealthy will cre­ate so much eco­nom­ic growth that the bill will pay for itself.

Trea­sury Sec­re­tary Steve Mnuchin recent­ly insist­ed [35] that “not only will this tax plan pay for itself, but it will pay down debt.” White House eco­nom­ic advis­er Gary Cohn agreed, say­ing [36] that “we can pay for the entire tax cut through growth over the cycle.”

Yet the new study by the Tax Pol­i­cy Cen­ter finds that while the bill would some­what boost the nation’s eco­nom­ic out­put, lead­ing to more rev­enue for the gov­ern­ment, it would not be enough to off­set the rev­enue lost by the tax cuts. The net effect of the bill would be to increase the deficit by $1.27 tril­lion over 10 years.

The esti­mat­ed growth would be low­er than promised and the impact would dimin­ish over time. The Tax Pol­i­cy Cen­ter esti­mates that the tax cuts would increase the U.S. GDP by 0.6 per­cent in 2018, 0.3 per­cent in 2027, and 0.2 per­cent in 2037.

The rev­enue gen­er­at­ed by the growth would be about $169 bil­lion over 10 years—a drop in the buck­et to the rev­enue the gov­ern­ment would lose over that same peri­od.

This study echoes the find­ings of oth­er analyses—including one con­duct­ed by Pres­i­dent Trump’s alma mater, the Whar­ton School of Busi­ness [37]—show­ing that even when tak­ing growth into account through so-called dynam­ic scor­ing, the tax bill would still bal­loon the deficit.

...
———-

“Study: Even With Dynam­ic Scor­ing, GOP Tax Bill Still Blows Up The Deficit” by Alice Oll­stein; Talk­ing Points Memo; 11/20/2017 [32]

“Yet the new study by the Tax Pol­i­cy Cen­ter finds that while the bill would some­what boost the nation’s eco­nom­ic out­put, lead­ing to more rev­enue for the gov­ern­ment, it would not be enough to off­set the rev­enue lost by the tax cuts. The net effect of the bill would be to increase the deficit by $1.27 tril­lion over 10 years

Even with assumed increas­es in eco­nom­ic growth as a result of these tax cuts, the Tax Pol­i­cy Cen­ter study found the net effect on the deficit would be an increase of $1.27 tril­lion over 10 years.

So if the Joint Com­mit­tee on Tax­a­tion is going to con­clude that the Sen­ate bill does actu­al­ly fol­low the Byrd rule, it’s going to have to assume that these tax cuts result in far greater enhanced eco­nom­ic growth than what the Tax Pol­i­cy Cen­ter was assum­ing. Spec­tu­lar growth. The kind of growth that the GOP has been promis­ing from its var­i­ous tax cuts for the rich for decades that nev­er seem to mate­r­i­al. That kind of growth.

Which is per­haps why it’s not sur­pris­ing to see state­ments like this com­ing from the Trump admin­is­tra­tion:

...
Trea­sury Sec­re­tary Steve Mnuchin recent­ly insist­ed [35] that “not only will this tax plan pay for itself, but it will pay down debt.” White House eco­nom­ic advis­er Gary Cohn agreed, say­ing [36] that “we can pay for the entire tax cut through growth over the cycle.”
...

That’s right, Trump’s Trea­sury Sec­re­tary actu­al­ly argued that the tax cuts will not only pay for itself but actu­al­ly bring in more rev­enue than it costs. Super trick-down! And the White House eco­nom­ic advi­sor Gary Cohn agreed! All those pro­jec­tions that the Sen­ate tax cut bill will result in over a tril­lion dol­lars in new deficits over the next decade are com­plete­ly wrong because the tax cuts will com­plete­ly pay for them­selves through eco­nom­ic growth accord­ing to the Trump White House [36]:

CNBC

Trump advi­sor Gary Cohn says we can pay for the entire tax cut through eco­nom­ic growth

* Tax cuts Repub­li­cans pro­posed this week will be paid for through eco­nom­ic growth, chief White House eco­nom­ic advi­sor Gary Cohn tells CNBC.
* Cohn says the cuts will dri­ve growth that will exceed 3 per­cent.

Jeff Cox
Pub­lished 8:05 AM ET Thu, 28 Sept 2017 Updat­ed 9:11 AM ET Thu, 28 Sept 2017

Tax cuts Repub­li­cans pro­posed this week will be paid for entire­ly through eco­nom­ic growth, chief White House eco­nom­ic advi­sor Gary Cohn said Thurs­day.

Repub­li­cans issued the tax over­haul plan [38] Wednes­day that sim­pli­fies the tax code, break­ing rates down into three cat­e­gories and cut­ting cor­po­rate rates. The plan also seeks to give com­pa­nies a break for prof­its stashed over­seas while dou­bling the stan­dard deduc­tion for most fil­ers.

The tax cuts are pro­ject­ed to cost at least $1.5 tril­lion and up to $2.2 tril­lion, accord­ing to one analy­sis. Tax reform, along with reduced reg­u­la­tion and infra­struc­ture spend­ing, was the cor­ner­stone of Pres­i­dent Don­ald Trump’s 2016 elec­tion cam­paign.

Cohn said the cuts won’t increase the bud­get deficit.

“We think we can dri­ve a lot of busi­ness back to Amer­i­ca, we can dri­ve jobs back to Amer­i­ca, we can make our­selves very com­pet­i­tive,” Cohn told CNBC in a live inter­view. “We think we can pay for the entire tax cut through growth over the cycle.”

Cohn pre­dict­ed that eco­nom­ic growth would be “sub­stan­tial­ly over 3 per­cent” due to tax reform and dereg­u­la­tion.

The GOP plan pro­pos­es low­er­ing the cor­po­rate tax rate from the cur­rent 35 per­cent, the high­est in the world, to 20 per­cent. The admin­is­tra­tion orig­i­nal­ly had want­ed 15 per­cent, and Cohn said the White House will not budge on the 20 per­cent lev­el [39].

...

———-

“Trump advi­sor Gary Cohn says we can pay for the entire tax cut through eco­nom­ic growth” by Jeff Cox; CNBC; 09/28/2017 [36]

““We think we can dri­ve a lot of busi­ness back to Amer­i­ca, we can dri­ve jobs back to Amer­i­ca, we can make our­selves very com­pet­i­tive,” Cohn told CNBC in a live inter­view. “We think we can pay for the entire tax cut through growth over the cycle.

This is seri­ous­ly the White House­’s line on this debate: there is no prob­lem with the Sen­ate’s com­pli­ance with the Byrd rule because the mas­sive tax cut for the rich and cor­po­ra­tions will com­plete­ly pay for itself.

Amer­i­ca’s CEO’s Did­n’t Get the Trick­le Down Memo

So giv­en that the White House is mak­ing some sort of Super Tricke-Down argu­ment to the pub­lic, it rais­es the ques­tion as to whether or not that’s the same argu­ment the GOP is plan­ning on mak­ing to the JCT. Is Super Trick­le-Down going to be offi­cial jus­ti­fi­ca­tion for this tax bill? Well, if so, some­one needs to inform Amer­i­ca’s CEOs. Because if Amer­i­can com­pa­nies expect­ed to go on an invest­ment and hir­ing binge after this tax cut goes into effect, Amer­i­ca’s CEOs don’t appear to be aware of this plan [40]:

Busi­ness Insid­er

Gary Cohn had an awk­ward moment when CEOs appeared to shoot down one of the biggest argu­ments for the GOP tax plan

Bob Bryan
Nov. 14, 2017, 1:58 PM

* The Trump admin­is­tra­tion has argued that the pro­posed GOP tax cuts will lead to a boom in pri­vate invest­ment.
* Dur­ing an event with the top White House eco­nom­ic advis­er, Gary Cohn, CEOs were asked whether they would increase invest­ment if the GOP’s tax over­haul passed.
* Few did, prompt­ing Cohn to ask, “Why aren’t the oth­er hands up?”

A group of CEOs on Tues­day appeared to cast doubt on one of the White House­’s biggest argu­ments for over­haul­ing the tax code — right in front of the eco­nom­ic advis­er Gary Cohn.

At a meet­ing of The Wall Street Jour­nal’s CEO Coun­cil, an inter­view with Cohn — the Nation­al Eco­nom­ic Coun­cil direc­tor who pre­vi­ous­ly worked as an exec­u­tive at Gold­man Sachs — prompt­ed dis­cus­sion about the amount of invest­ment the GOP tax bill, the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act [41], would gen­er­ate.

Repub­li­cans and the Trump admin­is­tra­tion have argued that tax cuts for busi­ness­es would lead com­pa­nies to invest­ment more [42] and raise wages for work­ers.

The mod­er­a­tor then asked those in atten­dance whether they were plan­ning to increase their busi­ness invest­ment if the tax bill became law. The CEOs in atten­dance did not seem to be on the same wave­length as Cohn.

While there was a smat­ter­ing of raised hands in the audi­to­ri­um, it was clear­ly not as many as Cohn would have liked.

“Why aren’t the oth­er hands up?” Cohn asked before mov­ing on to anoth­er ques­tion.

...

———-

“Gary Cohn had an awk­ward moment when CEOs appeared to shoot down one of the biggest argu­ments for the GOP tax plan” by Bob Bryan; Busi­ness Insid­er; 11/14/2017 [40]

“The mod­er­a­tor then asked those in atten­dance whether they were plan­ning to increase their busi­ness invest­ment if the tax bill became law. The CEOs in atten­dance did not seem to be on the same wave­length as Cohn.”

A smat­ter­ing of raised hands. That was the response from an audi­to­ri­um filled with CEOs at the Wall Street Jour­nal’s CEO Coun­cil when asked who was plan­ning on using this tax cut to hire more peo­ple:

...
While there was a smat­ter­ing of raised hands in the audi­to­ri­um, it was clear­ly not as many as Cohn would have liked.

“Why aren’t the oth­er hands up?” Cohn asked before mov­ing on to anoth­er ques­tion.
...

“Why aren’t the oth­er hands up?” It’s a ques­tion Amer­i­ca is prob­a­bly going to ask itself for years to come if that tax plan becomes real­i­ty. While deficits explode and wealth inequal­i­ty sky­rock­ets.

The Byrd Rule is Real­ly Just a Sug­ges­tion in the Long Run

But anoth­er ques­tion Amer­i­ca is prob­a­bly going to be ask­ing itself is, “how on Earth did we believe the deficits would only spike by $1 to 2 tril­lion?” Because in addi­tion to the Super Trick­le-Down argu­ments that we’re hear­ing from the White House, the GOP is trot­ting out anoth­er set of argu­ments to answer crit­ics who point out the tem­po­rary tax cuts are for the poor and mid­dle-class while all the per­ma­nent tax cuts are for cor­po­ra­tions and the wealthy: don’t wor­ry, those tem­po­rary tax cuts for the poor and mid­dle-class aren’t actu­al­ly tem­po­rary, because Con­gress will almost sure­ly extend them in the future. In oth­er words, all this talk about mak­ing the Sen­ate tax plan com­ply with the Byrd rule and remain deficit-neu­tral is pure­ly for expe­di­en­cy, and the real plan is to actu­al­ly blow up the deficit much, much more than even more than cur­rent­ly pro­ject­ed [43]:

The New York Times
The Con­science of a Lib­er­al

Schroedinger’s Tax Hike

Paul Krug­man
Novem­ber 24, 2017 12:26 pm Novem­ber 24, 2017 12:26 pm

Yes, I know that’s sup­posed to be an umlaut in the title. I just can’t per­suade Word­Press to do it.

So: There are many amaz­ing things about the Repub­li­can tax pitch, where by “amaz­ing” I mean ter­ri­ble. But pos­si­ble the most amaz­ing of all is the attempt to have it both ways on the ques­tion of mid­dle-class tax­es.

The Sen­ate bill, as writ­ten, tries to be long-run deficit-neu­tral — allow­ing use of the Byrd rule to bypass a fil­i­buster — by off­set­ting huge cor­po­rate tax cuts with high­er tax­es on indi­vid­u­als, so that by 2027 half the pop­u­la­tion, and most of the mid­dle-class [44], would see tax­es go up. But those tax hikes are ini­tial­ly off­set by a vari­ety of tem­po­rary tax breaks.

Now, Repub­li­cans are argu­ing that those tax breaks won’t actu­al­ly be tem­po­rary, that future Con­gress­es will extend them. But they also need to assume that those tax breaks real­ly will expire in order to meet their bud­get num­bers. So the tem­po­rary tax breaks need, for polit­i­cal pur­pos­es, to be both alive and dead.

If they suc­ceed in this exer­cise in quan­tum bud­get­ing, we’ll even­tu­al­ly open the box, col­laps­ing the wave func­tion, and dis­cov­er whether the bud­get promise or the tax claim was a lie. But for now, they want to hold it all in sus­pen­sion. Once upon a time you wouldn’t have imag­ined they could get away with it. Now …

———-

“Schroedinger’s Tax Hike” by Paul Krug­man; The New York Times; 11/24/2017 [43]

Now, Repub­li­cans are argu­ing that those tax breaks won’t actu­al­ly be tem­po­rary, that future Con­gress­es will extend them. But they also need to assume that those tax breaks real­ly will expire in order to meet their bud­get num­bers. So the tem­po­rary tax breaks need, for polit­i­cal pur­pos­es, to be both alive and dead.”

Don’t wor­ry about the deficit because enough of tax cuts are tem­po­rary. And don’t wor­ry about the unfair­ness of the tem­po­rary tax cuts because they aren’t actu­al­ly going to be tem­po­rary. This is the mes­sag­ing com­ing from the GOP right now, which is why even some con­ser­v­a­tives are get­ting anx­ious. You might be tempt­ed to assume that lots of GOP­ers would be get­ting ner­vous about this since focus­ing on the deficit is a cud­gel the GOP has been using for years to keep gov­ern­ment spend­ing down. But it turns out there aren’t actu­al­ly very many Repub­li­cans in Con­gress who care about high­er deficits if those deficits are a con­se­quence of a tax cut. But for that hand­ful of gen­uine GOP deficit hawks, all this talk about extend­ing the tem­po­rary tax cuts is mak­ing them ner­vous [45]:

Politi­co

GOP deficit hawks fear tax plan is secret bud­get-buster

Key Sen­ate Repub­li­cans wor­ry tax cuts slat­ed to expire will even­tu­al­ly be extend­ed — boost­ing the true cost of the bill.

By SEUNG MIN KIM

11/24/2017 07:42 AM EST

The GOP has yet to resolve an inter­nal clash over whether expir­ing tax cuts will real­ly expire, poten­tial­ly threat­en­ing the party’s push for a des­per­ate­ly-need­ed leg­isla­tive achieve­ment.

On one side are the White House and top con­gres­sion­al Repub­li­cans, who argue that ulti­mate­ly all the tax cuts in their plan will be extend­ed, even the ones slat­ed to lapse. But that’s exact­ly what the party’s small, but mighty, bloc of deficit hawks is afraid of.

And as the Sen­ate steams toward a vote next week on its mas­sive tax over­haul, the fight over the bill’s true stick­er price may be the decid­ing fac­tor for the bill.

It was bad enough, in the deficit hawks’ view, that key pro­vi­sions in the House bill expire in five years and that law­mak­ers already assume they’ll get extend­ed. But their con­cerns mul­ti­plied after the revised Sen­ate GOP tax plan pro­posed wind­ing down a host of pop­u­lar tax cuts for indi­vid­u­als after 2025. The tax cuts were made tem­po­rary to trim the offi­cial cost of the bill, but deficit hawks fear Con­gress will sim­ply extend them — fur­ther adding to the government’s red ink.

“The sav­ings, the score, it just isn’t valid because you know that they’re not going to fol­low through,” Sen. Jeff Flake (R‑Ariz.), an avowed fis­cal con­ser­v­a­tive, said in a recent inter­view. “You can’t assume that we’ll grow a back­bone lat­er. If we can’t do it now, then it’s tough to do it lat­er.”

The col­li­sion between what most Repub­li­cans see as sim­ple polit­i­cal real­i­ty — keep­ing pop­u­lar tax cuts for vot­ers — and deep deficit wor­ries from influ­en­tial GOP sen­a­tors could derail the tax reform efforts, par­tic­u­lar­ly if and when the cham­bers try to meld their tax pro­pos­als in the com­ing weeks.

The deficit hawks decry what they see as gim­micks in the plan, par­tic­u­lar­ly writ­ing in an expi­ra­tion date for tax breaks with no inten­tion of let­ting them die. While the offi­cial price tag for the Sen­ate tax plan may be $1.4 tril­lion, extend­ing all the expir­ing pro­vi­sions would bump up that cost by anoth­er half a tril­lion dol­lars, accord­ing to the fis­cal watch­dog group Com­mit­tee for a Respon­si­ble Fed­er­al Bud­get.

Repub­li­cans lead­ing the tax charge have said that the tax cuts expire mere­ly to fit with­in the para­me­ters set up by com­pli­cat­ed Sen­ate rules. And they brush off attacks from Democ­rats who note that the cuts are per­ma­nent for cor­po­ra­tions but tem­po­rary for reg­u­lar peo­ple. Repub­li­cans say Democ­rats should help them make those cuts per­ma­nent, which would require 60 votes on the floor — some­thing Democ­rats are unlike­ly to do.

Speak­er Paul Ryan (R‑Wis.) has pub­licly blamed the Sen­ate rules as the rea­son some pro­vi­sions in the House bill, like a fam­i­ly tax cred­it, expire after five years. He recent­ly told reporters he thinks future Con­gress­es will extend them.

That’s the White House line, too.

“Of course, the hope for every­body is that when the time comes for these things to expire, that they get extend­ed,” Kevin Has­sett, chair­man of the White House Coun­cil of Eco­nom­ic Advis­ers, said last week.

Flake and Ten­nessee Sen. Bob Cork­er, anoth­er inde­pen­dent-mind­ed Repub­li­can not run­ning for reelec­tion next year, have been among the most out­spo­ken with their deficit con­cerns. So too, has Sen. John McCain of Ari­zona, a major wild­card for GOP lead­er­ship in the tax fight.

But oth­er Repub­li­cans have grad­u­al­ly become more vocal about their own deficit wor­ries, with Sens. Todd Young of Indi­ana and James Lank­ford of Okla­homa among them. GOP lead­ers can only lose two votes before the tax bill tanks.

...

Oth­er GOP sen­a­tors have raised dif­fer­ent objec­tions to the tax bill; Sen. Ron John­son of Wis­con­sin doesn’t like the way the plan treats small busi­ness­es and Sen. Susan Collins of Maine takes issue with repeal­ing Obamacare’s indi­vid­ual man­date in the plan, among oth­er con­cerns.

Democ­rats have seized on the bill’s con­tra­dic­tions, and Sen­ate Minor­i­ty Leader Chuck Schumer of New York has been par­tic­u­lar­ly eager to exploit the Repub­li­can divide.

“I say to my col­leagues, par­tic­u­lar­ly the deficit hawks, you can’t have it both ways,” Schumer said in a recent floor speech. “You can­not say we’re going to pro­tect the mid­dle class after 2025 and we’re going to reduce the deficit. This bill is a deficit bud­get buster. We all know what will hap­pen.”

Indeed, Con­gress has a good track record of keep­ing expir­ing tax cuts around.

Law­mak­ers faced a “fis­cal cliff” at the end of 2012 com­posed main­ly of the expir­ing Bush tax cuts. Con­gress, backed by the Oba­ma admin­is­tra­tion, ulti­mate­ly vot­ed to make the vast major­i­ty of tax cuts per­ma­nent. Capi­tol Hill also rou­tine­ly vot­ed to main­tain tem­po­rary tax “exten­ders” year after year, before pass­ing leg­is­la­tion in Decem­ber 2015 that made most of them per­ma­nent.

The Sen­ate tax mea­sure includes dozens of pro­vi­sions that are set to expire yet would like­ly be polit­i­cal­ly unten­able to actu­al­ly kill; chief among them are their plans to boost the child tax cred­it, cut indi­vid­ual tax rates and increase the stan­dard deduc­tion.

Cork­er has been one of the loud­est crit­ics of bal­loon­ing the deficit. But he’s been care­ful not to open­ly dis­par­age the tax plans mov­ing through Con­gress, and Sen­ate tax-writ­ers, as well as lead­er­ship, are aware of his con­cerns. The Ten­nessee Repub­li­can said he has been dis­cussing ways to resolve deficit wor­ries with oth­er sen­a­tors — Flake among them — but declined to elab­o­rate fur­ther.

Whether Sen­ate Repub­li­cans can ulti­mate­ly win over the GOP skep­tics is unclear.

When asked about the cost of extend­ing expir­ing pro­vi­sions, McCain stressed: “I’m always wor­ried about the deficit.”

———-

“GOP deficit hawks fear tax plan is secret bud­get-buste” by SEUNG MIN KIM; Politi­co; 11/24/2017 [45]

“The deficit hawks decry what they see as gim­micks in the plan, par­tic­u­lar­ly writ­ing in an expi­ra­tion date for tax breaks with no inten­tion of let­ting them die. While the offi­cial price tag for the Sen­ate tax plan may be $1.4 tril­lion, extend­ing all the expir­ing pro­vi­sions would bump up that cost by anoth­er half a tril­lion dol­lars, accord­ing to the fis­cal watch­dog group Com­mit­tee for a Respon­si­ble Fed­er­al Bud­get.”

Extend­ing the tax expir­ing tax cuts for the poor and mid­dle-class is expect­ed to raise the cost of the Sen­ate’s plan from $1.4 tril­lion to close to $2 tril­lion, spik­ing the cost by over a third. And that $1.4 tril­lion is just the costs for the first 10 years. The long term costs of extend­ing the expir­ing tax cuts for the mid­dle-class will of course be sub­stan­tial­ly high­er if these tax cuts get the same treat­ment the cor­po­rate tax cuts are giv­en and are extend­ed per­ma­nent­ly.

So will the GOP’s ‘deficit hawks’ balk at the prospect of mas­sive­ly explod­ing the deficit for decades to come, some­thing that would guar­an­tee the forced cuts in enti­tle­ment pro­grams? We’ll see, but it’s worth not­ing that the three deficit hawks inter­viewed for the above arti­cle are three GOP­ers set to retire from the Sen­ate: Bob Cork­er, Jeff Flake, and John McCain:

...
Cork­er has been one of the loud­est crit­ics of bal­loon­ing the deficit. But he’s been care­ful not to open­ly dis­par­age the tax plans mov­ing through Con­gress, and Sen­ate tax-writ­ers, as well as lead­er­ship, are aware of his con­cerns. The Ten­nessee Repub­li­can said he has been dis­cussing ways to resolve deficit wor­ries with oth­er sen­a­tors — Flake among them — but declined to elab­o­rate fur­ther.

Whether Sen­ate Repub­li­cans can ulti­mate­ly win over the GOP skep­tics is unclear.

When asked about the cost of extend­ing expir­ing pro­vi­sions, McCain stressed: “I’m always wor­ried about the deficit.”

So will retir­ing from the Sen­ate make these three GOP­ers more like­ly to vote down the GOP’s prized tax cut out of sense of fis­cal respon­si­bil­i­ty, or will retir­ing just make it eas­i­er for these Sen­a­tors to vote for a bill that will like­ly cause hav­oc on the bud­get after they’ve retired? We’ll see.

GOP Mega-Donors, the Ulti­mate Con­stituen­cy

But one aspect of being a retir­ing Sen­a­tor should make life much eas­i­er for peo­ple like Bob Cork­er, Jeff Flake, and John McCain: they don’t have to answer to the GOP mega-donors [46]:

Talk­ing Points Memo
Livewire

GOP­er On Tax Cuts: Donors Are Say­ing ‘Get It Done Or Don’t Ever Call Me Again’

By Matt Shuham
Pub­lished Novem­ber 7, 2017 1:53 pm

Rep. Chris Collins (R‑NY) got points for hon­esty Tues­day while advo­cat­ing for Repub­li­cans’ tax bill to slash the cor­po­rate tax rate and elim­i­nate the estate tax, among oth­er things.

“My donors are basi­cal­ly say­ing, ‘Get it done or don’t ever call me again,’” Collins said.

Accord­ing to the Hill [47], Collins made the com­ment while speak­ing to reporters after a House GOP con­fer­ence meet­ing.

...

Collins, a mil­lion­aire and one of the wealth­i­est mem­bers of Con­gress, repeat­ed [48] the GOP claim in a radio inter­view Tues­day that a mid­dle-income Amer­i­can fam­i­ly would get a rough­ly $1,200 tax break as a result of the party’s tax pro­pos­al.

Vox’s Matthew Igle­sias report­ed Mon­day [15] that claim is only true for the first year fol­low­ing the plan’s pas­sage. The adver­tised tax break would decrease to next-to-noth­ing with­in six years, and the exem­plar fam­i­ly would pay more under Repub­li­cans’ tax bill from year sev­en onward.

———-

“GOP­er On Tax Cuts: Donors Are Say­ing ‘Get It Done Or Don’t Ever Call Me Again’” by Matt Shuham; Talk­ing Points Memo; 11/07/2017 [46]

““My donors are basi­cal­ly say­ing, ‘Get it done or don’t ever call me again,’” Collins said.”

Sure, that’s just an anec­dote from a sin­gle con­gress­man. But it’s hard to imag­ine that this isn’t the same mes­sage all GOP­ers are get­ting from their mega-donors across the coun­try. After all, it’s not like a tax cut that’s almost entire­ly for the rich and cor­po­ra­tion is going to be polit­i­cal­ly pop­u­lar. Yet the GOP is clear­ly des­per­ate to make this polit­i­cal poi­son pill a real­i­ty.

And yes, Trump and the GOP still clear­ly need at least one big leg­isla­tive ‘win’. But it’s hard to see how a tax cut that starts erod­ing away for the poor and mid­dle-class in a year is going to be polit­i­cal­ly help­ful. Mega-donors would­n’t need to issue ‘pass this, or else’ threats if it was a polit­i­cal win­ner. If Con­gress sim­ply passed a res­o­lu­tion to be bet­ter peo­ple next year that would be a far, far big­ger leg­isla­tive accom­plish­ment for the GOP than a super-vil­lain-ish tax mon­stros­i­ty.

Mis­in­formed Future Vot­ers Who Won’t Real­ize the Dam­age the GOP Has Already Done is Also an Impor­tant GOP Con­stituen­cy

So giv­en how polit­i­cal­ly poi­so­nous this hor­ri­ble tax plan is, it rais­es the ques­tion of what the GOP’s long-term plans are, espe­cial­ly giv­en the already declared plans to extend all the tax cuts and blow up the deficit even more. After all, if this bill pass­es and ends up being as polit­i­cal­ly poi­so­nous it appears to be, it’s entire­ly pos­si­ble that the GOP will lose con­trol of the House in 2018 and the Sen­ate and White House in 2020.

Does the GOP and its mega-donor class actu­al­ly believe in their Super Tricke-Down rhetoric? Do they actu­al­ly think there’s going to be an eco­nom­ic mega-boom that makes results in the tax cut pay­ing for itself? That seems high­ly unlike­ly. So what’s the plan?

Well, as the fol­low­ing arti­cle from Bruce Bartlett — a domes­tic pol­i­cy advi­sor for Ronald Rea­gan who helped pop­u­lar­ize the Trick­le-Down myth but who is now a harsh crit­ic of GOP eco­nom­ic pol­i­cy [49] — makes clear, the GOP plan is like­ly as fol­lows: pass a mas­sive tax cut now, lose con­trol of pow­er and the Democ­rats tem­porar­i­ly take con­trol while deficits explode from the tax cuts, then cam­paign against the Democ­rats as out-of-con­trol spenders who need to be thrown out of office for their fis­cal irre­spon­si­bil­i­ty, and final­ly regain polit­i­cal pow­er and demand mas­sive spend­ing cuts. In oth­er words, ‘the plan’ the same plan the GOP has been suc­cess­ful­ly exploit­ing for decades [50]:

The Guardian

Repub­li­can tax cuts will hurt Amer­i­cans. And Democ­rats will pay the price

The con­se­quences of the tax pro­gram will shelve sup­port for the Repub­li­cans, but once in pow­er the Democ­rats’ hands will be finan­cial­ly bound for years

Bruce Bartlett
Mon­day 20 Novem­ber 2017 09.10 EST
Last mod­i­fied on Mon­day 20 Novem­ber 2017 10.35 EST

I think many Democ­rats and inde­pen­dent polit­i­cal observers are puz­zled by the inten­si­ty with which Repub­li­cans are pur­su­ing their tax cut [51]. It’s not polit­i­cal­ly pop­u­lar and may well lead to the party’s defeat in next year’s con­gres­sion­al elec­tions. So why do it?

The answer is that Repub­li­cans are push­ing the tax cut at break­neck speed pre­cise­ly because they know they are prob­a­bly going to lose next year and in 2020 as well. The tax cut, once enact­ed, how­ev­er, will bind the hands of Democ­rats for years to come, forc­ing them to essen­tial­ly fol­low a Repub­li­can agen­da of deficit reduc­tion and pre­vent any action on a pos­i­tive Demo­c­ra­t­ic pro­gram. The result will be a steady ero­sion of sup­port for Democ­rats that will put Repub­li­cans back in pow­er with­in a few elec­tion cycles.

The the­o­ry was laid out almost 30 years ago by two Swedish econ­o­mists, Torsten Pers­son and Lars EO Svens­son. In a dense­ly writ­ten arti­cle [52] for the Quar­ter­ly Jour­nal of Eco­nom­ics in 1989, they explained why a stub­born con­ser­v­a­tive leg­is­la­tor would inten­tion­al­ly run a big bud­get deficit.

It has to do with what econ­o­mists call time incon­sis­ten­cy – the con­se­quences of actions tak­en today may not appear until the future, when a dif­fer­ent polit­i­cal par­ty will be in pow­er. Thus the cred­it or blame will accrue to that par­ty rather than the one that imple­ment­ed the pol­i­cy, because vot­ers tend to attribute what­ev­er is hap­pen­ing today to the par­ty in pow­er today even if that par­ty had noth­ing to do with it.

Thus Barack Oba­ma got blamed for a reces­sion and result­ing bud­get deficits he had noth­ing to do with orig­i­nat­ing. No mat­ter how many times the Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office showed that the vast bulk of the bud­get deficits in his admin­is­tra­tion were baked in the cake the day he took office, Repub­li­cans nev­er­the­less blamed him and his poli­cies exclu­sive­ly for those deficits.

Of course, anoth­er rea­son for those deficits is that Repub­li­cans sys­tem­at­i­cal­ly dec­i­mat­ed the fed­er­al government’s rev­enue-rais­ing capac­i­ty dur­ing the George W Bush admin­is­tra­tion with one huge tax cut after anoth­er. All of these were sold as nec­es­sary to get the econ­o­my grow­ing again. The fail­ure of the econ­o­my to respond pos­i­tive­ly was nev­er tak­en as evi­dence of the fail­ure of those tax cuts, but rather as show­ing the need for even more and big­ger tax cuts.

The pay­off for this orgy of tax-cut­ting came when Oba­ma took office. All of a sud­den, Repub­li­cans noticed that there were large deficits and insist­ed that Oba­ma do some­thing about them right this minute! They even made the non­sen­si­cal argu­ment that spend­ing cuts would stim­u­late growth by reduc­ing the bur­den of gov­ern­ment.

Democ­rats did a poor job of explain­ing how Franklin Roo­sevelt tried exact­ly that in 1937, slash­ing gov­ern­ment spend­ing because his trea­sury sec­re­tary told him it would restore busi­ness con­fi­dence. The result was a sharp down­turn that raised unem­ploy­ment, which had been trend­ing down.

Obama’s hands were tied by the deficit hawks in his own par­ty as well and pre­vent­ed from offer­ing an eco­nom­ic stim­u­lus ade­quate to off­set the loss of aggre­gate demand result­ing from the great reces­sion that began in Decem­ber 2007 on Bush’s watch. Oba­ma even joined with Repub­li­cans to slash spend­ing in the 2011 bud­get deal and put in place bud­get con­trols that made it vir­tu­al­ly impos­si­ble to pur­sue any pos­i­tive Demo­c­ra­t­ic ini­tia­tives for the bal­ance of his pres­i­den­cy. No won­der Trump won.

I think Repub­li­cans remem­ber bet­ter than Democ­rats the les­son of 1993 as well. Bill Clin­ton was elect­ed in 1992 on an activist agen­da. But once in office, he was per­suad­ed to reverse course and put all his efforts into deficit reduc­tion. This trans­for­ma­tion was spelled out in detail in Bob Woodward’s 1994 book, The Agen­da [53]. Its key ele­ment was a sig­nif­i­cant tax increase that every Repub­li­can in Con­gress vot­ed against. They said it would crash the econ­o­my, but was instead fol­lowed by an eco­nom­ic boom. Unfor­tu­nate­ly, the boom didn’t become appar­ent until after the 1994 elec­tion in which Democ­rats took heavy loss­es – in large part because of the tax increase. Repub­li­cans got con­trol of both hous­es of Con­gress for the first time in 40 years.

Clin­ton remained behold­en to the deficit hawks for his entire pres­i­den­cy, doing noth­ing with the vast bud­get sur­plus­es that emerged and hoard­ing them like a mod­ern day Midas, despite press­ing eco­nom­ic needs and grow­ing finan­cial prob­lems with­so­cial secu­ri­ty and Medicare that those sur­plus­es could have fixed. Clin­ton sim­ply bequeathed them to Bush, who prompt­ly dis­si­pat­ed them with tax cuts and a huge new spend­ing pro­gram, Medicare Part D, not to men­tion wars in the Mid­dle East that con­tin­ue to this day.

I believe that the same cycle will rerun over the next few years. Should Democ­rats get con­trol of the House and/or Sen­ate next year, Trump and his par­ty will insist that deficit reduc­tion be the only order of busi­ness. Auto­mat­ic spend­ing cuts result­ing direct­ly from the tax cut will start to bite, hurt­ing the poor and mid­dle class pri­mar­i­ly, accord­ing to the Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office, and mak­ing them for­get that they result­ed from a huge tax give-away to the wealthy that increased the deficit by $1.5tn. Democ­rats will get much of the blame due to time-incon­sis­ten­cy.

It’s pos­si­ble that Trump’s appointees to the Fed­er­al Reserve may be so alarmed by the infla­tion­ary poten­tial of the grow­ing deficits that they will raise inter­est rates in response. This could trig­ger a reces­sion that will be blamed on a Demo­c­ra­t­ic pres­i­dent tak­ing office in 2021, just as hap­pened with Oba­ma. But that pres­i­dent may not be able to enact any stim­u­lus at all because deficits crowd out any fis­cal space. By 2022, Repub­li­cans will be back in con­trol of Con­gress and in the White House by 2024. In 2025, they will demand still more tax cuts.

Keep in mind that no mat­ter how big the deficit gets from the tax cut Repub­li­cans are rush­ing to enact, none of them will ever vote to undo those cuts or raise tax­es except, per­haps, in ways that fur­ther bur­den the poor, such as rais­ing the gaso­line tax. That is because they all signed a tax pledge promis­ing nev­er to raise tax­es. There­fore, any deficit reduc­tion will either con­sist sole­ly of spend­ing cuts or pass with only Demo­c­ra­t­ic votes, as was the case in 1993.

The orig­i­na­tor of the pledge, Grover Norquist, planned it this way. I doubt he has ever read Pers­son and Svens­son, but under­stood intu­itive­ly that the tax pledge was guar­an­teed to ratch­et down the size of gov­ern­ment for­ev­er. It wouldn’t hap­pen all at once, but over a peri­od of decades. The his­to­ry of fis­cal pol­i­cy since the pledge was orig­i­nat­ed in 1988 is, sad­ly, proof that it has worked exact­ly as he hoped.

...

———-

“Repub­li­can tax cuts will hurt Amer­i­cans. And Democ­rats will pay the price” by Bruce Bartlett; The Guardian; 11/20/2017 [50].

“I think many Democ­rats and inde­pen­dent polit­i­cal observers are puz­zled by the inten­si­ty with which Repub­li­cans are pur­su­ing their tax cut [51]. It’s not polit­i­cal­ly pop­u­lar and may well lead to the party’s defeat in next year’s con­gres­sion­al elec­tions. So why do it?

That’s the big ques­tion: why do it? Why is the GOP push­ing so hard to do some­thing that appears to be polit­i­cal sui­cide? And Bruce Bartlett has a very com­pelling answer: The GOP is inten­tion­al­ly com­mit­ting the polit­i­cal equiv­a­lent of a sui­cide-bomb­ing. It’s a strat­e­gy root­ed in the assump­tion that the pub­lic will have no mem­o­ry any of this ever hap­pened:

...
The answer is that Repub­li­cans are push­ing the tax cut at break­neck speed pre­cise­ly because they know they are prob­a­bly going to lose next year and in 2020 as well. The tax cut, once enact­ed, how­ev­er, will bind the hands of Democ­rats for years to come, forc­ing them to essen­tial­ly fol­low a Repub­li­can agen­da of deficit reduc­tion and pre­vent any action on a pos­i­tive Demo­c­ra­t­ic pro­gram. The result will be a steady ero­sion of sup­port for Democ­rats that will put Repub­li­cans back in pow­er with­in a few elec­tion cycles.

The the­o­ry was laid out almost 30 years ago by two Swedish econ­o­mists, Torsten Pers­son and Lars EO Svens­son. In a dense­ly writ­ten arti­cle [52] for the Quar­ter­ly Jour­nal of Eco­nom­ics in 1989, they explained why a stub­born con­ser­v­a­tive leg­is­la­tor would inten­tion­al­ly run a big bud­get deficit.

It has to do with what econ­o­mists call time incon­sis­ten­cy – the con­se­quences of actions tak­en today may not appear until the future, when a dif­fer­ent polit­i­cal par­ty will be in pow­er. Thus the cred­it or blame will accrue to that par­ty rather than the one that imple­ment­ed the pol­i­cy, because vot­ers tend to attribute what­ev­er is hap­pen­ing today to the par­ty in pow­er today even if that par­ty had noth­ing to do with it.
...

“It has to do with what econ­o­mists call time incon­sis­ten­cy – the con­se­quences of actions tak­en today may not appear until the future, when a dif­fer­ent polit­i­cal par­ty will be in pow­er. Thus the cred­it or blame will accrue to that par­ty rather than the one that imple­ment­ed the pol­i­cy, because vot­ers tend to attribute what­ev­er is hap­pen­ing today to the par­ty in pow­er today even if that par­ty had noth­ing to do with it.”

Blow­ing the par­ty up in order to cre­ate fis­cal con­di­tions that force the par­ty’s long-term goals and rely­ing on the the­o­ry of “time incon­sis­ten­cy” to ensure that vot­ers have no idea what hap­pened. That’s the plan.

And it’s plan with prece­dents. Very recent prece­dents:

...
Thus Barack Oba­ma got blamed for a reces­sion and result­ing bud­get deficits he had noth­ing to do with orig­i­nat­ing. No mat­ter how many times the Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office showed that the vast bulk of the bud­get deficits in his admin­is­tra­tion were baked in the cake the day he took office, Repub­li­cans nev­er­the­less blamed him and his poli­cies exclu­sive­ly for those deficits.

Of course, anoth­er rea­son for those deficits is that Repub­li­cans sys­tem­at­i­cal­ly dec­i­mat­ed the fed­er­al government’s rev­enue-rais­ing capac­i­ty dur­ing the George W Bush admin­is­tra­tion with one huge tax cut after anoth­er. All of these were sold as nec­es­sary to get the econ­o­my grow­ing again. The fail­ure of the econ­o­my to respond pos­i­tive­ly was nev­er tak­en as evi­dence of the fail­ure of those tax cuts, but rather as show­ing the need for even more and big­ger tax cuts.

The pay­off for this orgy of tax-cut­ting came when Oba­ma took office. All of a sud­den, Repub­li­cans noticed that there were large deficits and insist­ed that Oba­ma do some­thing about them right this minute! They even made the non­sen­si­cal argu­ment that spend­ing cuts would stim­u­late growth by reduc­ing the bur­den of gov­ern­ment.

Democ­rats did a poor job of explain­ing how Franklin Roo­sevelt tried exact­ly that in 1937, slash­ing gov­ern­ment spend­ing because his trea­sury sec­re­tary told him it would restore busi­ness con­fi­dence. The result was a sharp down­turn that raised unem­ploy­ment, which had been trend­ing down.
...

The Oba­ma pres­i­den­cy was an exam­ple of the suc­cess­ful imple­men­ta­tion of “time-incon­sis­ten­cy”. The George W. Bush admin­is­tra­tion pass all sorts of tax cuts for the rich that don’t mag­i­cal­ly result in a boom­ing econ­o­my, dereg­u­lates the finan­cial sec­tor, and by the time Oba­ma enters the White House the econ­o­my has tanked, deficits spiked, and the Democ­rats are unable to ade­quate­ly respond in fis­cal stim­u­lus. It’s an impor­tant les­son, not just because it was recent, but also because you almost could­n’t come up with a more appro­pri­ate sit­u­a­tion for deficit spend­ing than gov­ern­ment stim­u­lus fol­low­ing some­thing like the 2008 finan­cial cri­sis. But that option was sig­nif­i­cant­ly com­prised thanks to the Bush tax cuts.

And then, fol­low­ing the GOP re-tak­ing con­trol of the House in 2010, the GOP imme­di­ate­ly declares the bud­get is out of con­trol and even­tu­al­ly black­mail­ing the Democ­rats into accept­ing the sequester because the alter­na­tive would have been the GOP forc­ing a default on the nation­al debt [54]. And that same sequester is still in place today. This is why the $25 bil­lion in Medicare cuts might hap­pen as result of the pro­pose tax cuts: Repub­li­cans used the ris­ing deficits in Oba­ma’s ear­ly years fol­low­ing the 2008 finan­cial cri­sis — years when the deficit should have risen due to the sit­u­a­tion — to regain polit­i­cal pow­er and then take the nation’s finances hostage to force the Democ­rats into accept­ing the sequester. And the pub­lic large­ly has no idea this hap­pened. Time-incon­sis­ten­cy in action:

...
Obama’s hands were tied by the deficit hawks in his own par­ty as well and pre­vent­ed from offer­ing an eco­nom­ic stim­u­lus ade­quate to off­set the loss of aggre­gate demand result­ing from the great reces­sion that began in Decem­ber 2007 on Bush’s watch. Oba­ma even joined with Repub­li­cans to slash spend­ing in the 2011 bud­get deal and put in place bud­get con­trols that made it vir­tu­al­ly impos­si­ble to pur­sue any pos­i­tive Demo­c­ra­t­ic ini­tia­tives for the bal­ance of his pres­i­den­cy. No won­der Trump won.
...

And that’s just the prece­dent from the Oba­ma years. Then there’s the case of the Clin­ton admin­is­tra­tion: Bill Clin­ton gets elect­ed on an activist agen­da in 1992 but then sub­mits to a deficits reduc­tion strat­e­gy that involves rais­ing tax­es. That tax hike helps sweep the GOP into con­gres­sion­al pow­er in 1994, but it’s also great pol­i­cy and pre­cedes an eco­nom­ic boom that results in a surge in gov­ern­ment rev­enues. Clin­ton sticks with the bud­get-reduc­tion agen­da and even­tu­al­ly hands a bud­get sur­plus to George W. Bush, who prompt­ly pro­ceeds to con­vert it into a bud­get-bust­ing tax cut for the rich and Medicare Part D (which is basi­cal­ly a cor­po­rate give­away that fos­ters high drug prices) [55]:

...
I think Repub­li­cans remem­ber bet­ter than Democ­rats the les­son of 1993 as well. Bill Clin­ton was elect­ed in 1992 on an activist agen­da. But once in office, he was per­suad­ed to reverse course and put all his efforts into deficit reduc­tion. This trans­for­ma­tion was spelled out in detail in Bob Woodward’s 1994 book, The Agen­da [53]. Its key ele­ment was a sig­nif­i­cant tax increase that every Repub­li­can in Con­gress vot­ed against. They said it would crash the econ­o­my, but was instead fol­lowed by an eco­nom­ic boom. Unfor­tu­nate­ly, the boom didn’t become appar­ent until after the 1994 elec­tion in which Democ­rats took heavy loss­es – in large part because of the tax increase. Repub­li­cans got con­trol of both hous­es of Con­gress for the first time in 40 years.

Clin­ton remained behold­en to the deficit hawks for his entire pres­i­den­cy, doing noth­ing with the vast bud­get sur­plus­es that emerged and hoard­ing them like a mod­ern day Midas, despite press­ing eco­nom­ic needs and grow­ing finan­cial prob­lems with­so­cial secu­ri­ty and Medicare that those sur­plus­es could have fixed. Clin­ton sim­ply bequeathed them to Bush, who prompt­ly dis­si­pat­ed them with tax cuts and a huge new spend­ing pro­gram, Medicare Part D, not to men­tion wars in the Mid­dle East that con­tin­ue to this day.
...

Clin­ton rais­es tax­es, gets polit­i­cal­ly pun­ished for it, over­sees an eco­nom­ic boom, and hands a bud­get sur­plus to George W. Bush who blows it all on tax cuts, wars, and a Big Phar­ma give­away. Time-incon­sis­ten­cy strikes again.

And as Bruce Bar­lett warns us, this cycle is like­ly to play out again:

...
I believe that the same cycle will rerun over the next few years. Should Democ­rats get con­trol of the House and/or Sen­ate next year, Trump and his par­ty will insist that deficit reduc­tion be the only order of busi­ness. Auto­mat­ic spend­ing cuts result­ing direct­ly from the tax cut will start to bite, hurt­ing the poor and mid­dle class pri­mar­i­ly, accord­ing to the Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office, and mak­ing them for­get that they result­ed from a huge tax give-away to the wealthy that increased the deficit by $1.5tn. Democ­rats will get much of the blame due to time-incon­sis­ten­cy.
...

I believe that the same cycle will rerun over the next few years. Should Democ­rats get con­trol of the House and/or Sen­ate next year, Trump and his par­ty will insist that deficit reduc­tion be the only order of busi­ness. Auto­mat­ic spend­ing cuts result­ing direct­ly from the tax cut will start to bite, hurt­ing the poor and mid­dle class pri­mar­i­ly, accord­ing to the Con­gres­sion­al Bud­get Office, and mak­ing them for­get that they result­ed from a huge tax give-away to the wealthy that increased the deficit by $1.5tn. Democ­rats will get much of the blame due to time-incon­sis­ten­cy”

And that cycle that Bruce Bartlett warns us about is the cycle Grover [56] Norquist [57] has been pro­mot­ing for decades. In par­tic­u­lar, pro­mot­ing by get­ting GOP­ers to sign a ‘no tax’ pledge that means the GOP has pledged to not undo the dam­age it does even if its tax cut is super dam­ag­ing:

...
Keep in mind that no mat­ter how big the deficit gets from the tax cut Repub­li­cans are rush­ing to enact, none of them will ever vote to undo those cuts or raise tax­es except, per­haps, in ways that fur­ther bur­den the poor, such as rais­ing the gaso­line tax. That is because they all signed a tax pledge promis­ing nev­er to raise tax­es. There­fore, any deficit reduc­tion will either con­sist sole­ly of spend­ing cuts or pass with only Demo­c­ra­t­ic votes, as was the case in 1993.

The orig­i­na­tor of the pledge, Grover Norquist, planned it this way. I doubt he has ever read Pers­son and Svens­son, but under­stood intu­itive­ly that the tax pledge was guar­an­teed to ratch­et down the size of gov­ern­ment for­ev­er. It wouldn’t hap­pen all at once, but over a peri­od of decades. The his­to­ry of fis­cal pol­i­cy since the pledge was orig­i­nat­ed in 1988 is, sad­ly, proof that it has worked exact­ly as he hoped.

“There­fore, any deficit reduc­tion will either con­sist sole­ly of spend­ing cuts or pass with only Demo­c­ra­t­ic votes, as was the case in 1993.”

Yep, the Norquist cycle con­tin­ues:

1. The GOP engages in a fis­cal­ly egre­gious agen­da

2. The Democ­rats even­tu­al­ly regain con­trol after the GOP’s politi­cies cre­ate a finan­cial dis­as­ter and the GOP imme­di­ate­ly starts using ris­ing deficits to argue for cut­ting enti­tle­ments and pub­lic pro­grams

3. Democ­rats try to undo the GOP’s fis­cal dam­age, includ­ing with tax hikes, and get polit­i­cal­ly pun­ished

4. The GOP regains con­trol and imme­di­ate­ly for­gets about deficits and pur­sues its fis­cal­ly egre­gious agen­da. And Grover Norquist gets real­ly hap­py.

That’s been the polit­i­cal cycle play­ing out in the US ever since the GOP embraced ‘Reaganomics’ and the Myth of the Mag­i­cal Trick­le-Down Tax Cut. And this is Bruce Bartlett — one of the archi­tects of that myth [49] — who is remind­ing us of this cycle.

But as impor­tant as Bruce Bartlet­t’s les­son about the impend­ing trap that the GOP and its mega-donor pup­pet­mas­ters are lay­ing is for the Amer­i­can pub­lic at this moment, per­haps the most impor­tant les­son is that Bruce Bartlett need­ed to explain this les­son in the first place. Because this is just basic his­to­ry at this point. It was super help­ful that Bruce Bartlett wrote that arti­cle but it should­n’t be super help­ful because we should already all know this. But Amer­i­cans don’t know this and it’s that mass col­lec­tive amne­sia about sig­nif­i­cant issues — issues like how the GOP exploits mass amne­sia to wage a class war on behalf of fas­cist mega-donors — that allows this cycle to con­tin­ue with­out end. We’re so col­lec­tive­ly bad at learn­ing from his­to­ry that we haven’t even learned that we’re col­lec­tive­ly bad at learn­ing from his­to­ry. It’s hard to think of a more impor­tant les­son than the fact that the Amer­i­can pub­lic is large­ly inca­pable of learn­ing impor­tant lessons from con­tem­po­rary his­to­ry because that’s why this same scam keeps hap­pen­ing over and over.

Mass amne­sia over con­tem­po­rary his­to­ry is so pre­dictable in the US that the GOP and its mega-donors can plot a strat­e­gy pred­i­cat­ed on the above cycle pre­dictably play­ing out one more time. That’s the con­clu­sion Bruce Bartlett has arrived at and it seems like a very rea­son­able con­clu­sion. A plan pred­i­cat­ed on the assum­pi­on of mass amne­sia is a very GOP-ish plan to exe­cute. No mat­ter how Big the Lie gets with the GOP, the peo­ple for­get that it hap­pened. Or nev­er learn in the first place. And it just keeps hap­pen­ing over and over. Because if the time-incon­sis­ten­cy strat­e­gy works once it’s prob­a­bly going to keep work­ing over and over because it only works when the pub­lic does­n’t know its own his­to­ry. A polit­i­cal strat­e­gy of root­ed in the time-incon­sis­ten­cy the­o­ry is a polit­i­cal strat­e­gy root­ed in an aware­ness of a pub­lic mass lack of aware­ness of hap­pened. And that aware­ness that the GOP clear­ly pos­sess­es means GOP can reuse the time-incon­sis­ten­cy strat­e­gy over and over. Which the GOP appears to be doing. Again.

So, because the cur­rent tax mad­ness is just the lat­est iter­a­tion of an ongo­ing scam cycle root­ed in the exploita­tion of a poor nation­al mem­o­ry, it’s going to be impor­tant to keep in mind that rebuild­ing the capac­i­ty for a mean­ing­ful nation­al mem­o­ry should prob­a­bly be part of the nation­al response to the tax mon­stros­i­ty that’s about to be unleashed. Mak­ing a point of active­ly remem­ber­ing for years to come that the GOP unleashed a fis­cal time-bomb (for the ben­e­fit of the super-rich) is prob­a­bly one of the most valu­able things the Democ­rats and pub­lic at large can do if this tax bill becomes law.

Imag­ine a big polit­i­cal fight in a decade (or more like­liy 2024, or even 2020), over whether or not to make the tem­po­rary tax cuts for the poor and mid­dle-class per­ma­nent. Being able to remem­ber con­tem­po­rary his­to­ry — his­to­ry that includes the eco­nom­ic boom that fol­lowed the Clin­ton tax hikes — will be invalu­able in that kind of polit­i­cal sit­u­a­tion. Because thanks to these tax cuts and the dam­age they’re most assured­ly going to do to the fed­er­al bud­get, the US pub­lic is soon going to be fac­ing a stark choice over whether or not to raise tax­es or mas­sive­ly cut fed­er­al pro­grams like Medicare that the pub­lic loves. Don’t for­get, forc­ing stark choic­es like that and bet­ting that the Democ­rats and pub­lic won’t choose to raise tax­es and cut spend­ing instead is part of the GOP/Norquist long-term time-incon­sis­ten­cy plan too. And that’s why it’s going to be so impor­tant to devel­op a nation­al mem­o­ry capa­ble of recall­ing things like the fact that Demo­c­ra­t­ic tax hikes are done to fix GOP fis­cal dam­age and they’ve been large­ly suc­cess­ful.

The GOP is plan­ning on cre­at­ing a giant fis­cal mess that it knows Democ­rats are going to be forced to clean up and the GOP is plan­ning on using that as an oppor­tu­ni­ty to regain pow­er by bash­ing the Democ­rats for clean­ing up the mess. We know that’s like­ly the plan because it’s the same plan we’ve watched play out for decades to the GOP’s enor­mous suc­cess. And it’s going to remain the GOP’s plan as long as we keep col­lec­tive­ly for­get­ting that it remains the GOP’s plan.

While Bruce Bartlett is absolute­ly cor­rect that the best out­come is for the pub­lic to pre­vent this tax bill from becom­ing law in the first place, it’s also pret­ty clear that it real­ly could eas­i­ly become law at this point even if it’s going to dam­age the GOP to do so. Pass­ing fis­cal­ly dis­as­trous tax cuts for the wealthy and cor­po­ra­tions is one of the GOP’s core rea­sons for exist­ing. It’s what it does even when that’s not the best move polit­i­cal­ly because keep­ing mega-donors hap­py is the GOP’s long-term best polit­i­cal move. As Bar­lett point­ed out, the GOP is prob­a­bly plan­ning on los­ing in the House and Sen­ate in upcom­ing elec­tions and maybe even the White House too. Hand­ing con­trol back to the Democ­rats after cre­at­ing a fis­cal cri­sis is part of the cycle. Unless of hand­ful of GOP Sen­a­tors save the day it’s hard to see what’s going to stop it’s pas­sage.

And if it pass­es, the US is going to be fac­ing a gen­er­al set of choic­es

1. Trick­le-down eco­nom­ics mag­i­cal­ly start work­ing and the pro­ject­ed deficits nev­er mate­ri­al­ize. Hooray.

2. The pro­ject­ed deficits mate­ri­al­ize and pub­lic spend­ing is cut to deal with them.

3. The pro­ject­ed deficits mate­ri­al­ize and tax­es are raised to deal with them.

4. Some com­bi­na­tion of 2. and 3.

Unless ill-advised trick­le-down eco­nom­ics sud­den­ly works, the US is going to have to raise tax­es or cut spend­ing. And the GOP is bet­ting that even if the Democ­rats take con­trol in com­ing years they’ll still be pres­sured into cut­ting spend­ing instead of rais­ing tax­es.

So it’s prob­a­bly not too ear­ly to start lay­ing the ground­work for a polit­i­cal move­ment ded­i­cat­ed to build­ing the nation­al col­lec­tive aware­ness about the time-incon­sis­ten­cy the­o­ry of pol­i­tics and the fact the GOP has been employ­ing this the­o­ry for a long time. There is no log­i­cal rea­son the Democ­rats should be polit­i­cal­ly pun­ished for clean­ing up the GOP’s fis­cal mess­es reward­ed for rais­ing tax­es on the rich. Espe­cial­ly when polls show the Amer­i­can pub­lic would much rather see tax­es raised on cor­po­ra­tions and the wealthy, not low­ered dra­mat­i­cal­ly [58]. Which is a find­ing [59] polls [60] have shown [61] for [62] years [63]. When the Democ­rats are forced to raise tax­es to clean up the GOP’s giant fis­cal mess, there’s not rea­son that can’t be a pos­i­tive polit­i­cal move for Democ­rats too. But for that to hap­pen the Amer­i­can pub­lic needs to have a work­ing mem­o­ry of this same old scam cycle that this the GOP is try­ing to do right now and has done in the past.

So what bet­ter time than the present for a pub­lic edu­ca­tion cam­paign to teach the Amer­i­can pub­lic about the con­tem­po­rary his­to­ry of the GOP cre­at­ing fis­cal mess­es with tax cuts for the rich and the Democ­rats clean­ing up that mess and get­ting polit­i­cal­ly pun­ished for doing so. The his­to­ry of GOP tax scams is com­ing alive once again as it repeats itself, so the Amer­i­can pub­lic should prob­a­bly learn that his­to­ry this time around [64].